Elsevier

Journal of Retailing

Volume 96, Issue 4, December 2020, Pages 563-577
Journal of Retailing

Resale Price Maintenance: Customer Service Without Free Riding

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jretai.2020.05.001Get rights and content

Highlights

RPM is not always manufacturer-optimal.The optimal RPM strategy can entail a price ceiling or a price floor.The optimal RPM floor may only constrain one retailer.The optimal RPM strategy may increase the profits of the larger retailer.

Abstract

Recent judicial legalizations of resale price maintenance (RPM) allow a manufacturer to establish limits to the prices that its retailers charge: a maximum price (a ceiling) or a minimum price (a floor). A manufacturer can also choose not to apply an RPM constraint. To determine how RPM affects service levels and the distribution of profit between channel members, we derive the optimal RPM strategy for a manufacturer that sells through competing retailers who provide their own optimal level of demand-enhancing customer service. Our analysis yields four key insights into a manufacturer's use of RPM in the absence of free riding.

First, there are conditions for which a manufacturer benefits by applying either an RPM Ceiling or an RPM Floor, but there are also conditions that cause the manufacturer not to intervene in its retailers’ pricing decisions. Second, a manufacturer's use of RPM depends on how effectively its retailers provide service, and their service-effectiveness disparity. Third, intensity of inter-retailer competition affects the manufacturer's optimal application of RPM. Fourth, RPM Floors often enhance a large retailer's profit relative to the absence of RPM – but this does not hold for a small retailer. Our findings generate significant managerial implications, insights into the consequences of laws that allow manufacturers to limit their retailers’ pricing decisions. We also offer suggestions for future research.

Introduction

Resale price maintenance (RPM) refers to manufacturer policies that limit retailers’ pricing flexibility. With maximum RPM (a price ceiling), retailers can choose any price that is no higher than the ceiling (e.g., Blair and Lafontaine 1999). With minimum RPM (a price floor), retailers can charge any price that is no lower than the floor (Harbour and Price 2010). In the United States, a manufacturer can legally impose a ceiling or a floor, provided such restraints are not anticompetitive.

RPM's legality is recent. Ceilings were per se illegal from 1968–1997, as were floors from 1911–2007 (albeit with fair trade exceptions from 1937–1975). RPM Ceilings were subjected to the rule of reason in the US Supreme Court's State Oil decision in 1997; the Court reached the same conclusion on RPM Floors in its Leegin decision in 2007.1 While the State Oil case generated little controversy, critics of the Leegin case have raised several issues.

First, the split decision in the Leegin case relied on free riding to justify minimum RPM (Gundlach, Cannon, and Manning 2010). In his Leegin dissent, Justice Breyer stated: “the ultimate question is not whether, but how much, ‘free riding’ of this sort takes place” (2007, p. 9). Experts have opined that free riding is rather rare, noting that when RPM floors were illegal, manufacturers tried to impose RPM on products needing little or no service (Ippolito 1991). To illustrate, a former FTC chair wrote that when “state fair trade statutes authorized RPM agreements, minimum resale price maintenance was instituted with respect to … pet food, vitamins, hair shampoo, ammunition, blue jeans, and men's underwear” (Pitofsky 2007, p. 63). The thrust of these comments motivates our first and second research questions:

  • 1.

    Does a manufacturer ever benefit by applying an RPM rule in the absence of free riding?

  • 2.

    If a manufacturer does benefit, under what market conditions does it do so?

    Drawing on Pitofsky's examples, pet food is sold by retailers ranging from supermarkets to pet supply stores; similarly, hair shampoo is available at retailers as diverse as supercenters and upscale hair salons. These examples, which span service levels from near zero to quite high, motivate our third research question:

  • 3.

    Does a manufacturer's use of RPM depend on a disparity in retailers’ service effectiveness?

    The preceding examples also highlight that many products are sold by merchants that may have strong, moderate, or even weak competitors in their own line of trade, as well as competition from other lines of trade in specific product classes. This motivates our fourth research question:

  • 4.

    Does intensity of retailer competition affect the application of RPM by a manufacturer?

    In his Leegin dissent, Justice Breyer also noted that concentration “may enable (and motivate) more retailers, accounting for … a greater percentage of total retail sales volume, to seek resale price maintenance, thereby making it more difficult for price-cutting competitors … to obtain market share” (2007, p. 15). Justice Breyer's observation motivates our fifth research question:

  • 5.

    Does the imposition of RPM benefit large retailers?

To address these questions, we analyze a model of a manufacturer that sells through two competing retailers who control their own service levels. We examine the optimal use of RPM without free riding – unlike the preponderance of the RPM literature that focuses on ameliorating deleterious effects of free riding (e.g., Telser 1960). We show that a manufacturer-optimal RPM strategy reflects the interaction of three market conditions: competitive intensity, the effectiveness of the most proficient retailer's service, and the disparity in retailers’ service effectiveness. We prove that a manufacturer can increase its profit by imposing RPM on its dealers under many – but not all – market conditions. Moreover, a large retailer can often gain from RPM floors – justifying Justice Breyer's concern with retail concentration.

Our model's central tension is the profit tradeoff between raising service by forcing prices higher with a floor versus diminishing service with a ceiling to minimize markups above cost. Excessive markups dissipate profit, but so does insufficient service. When service effectiveness is low, a price ceiling can amplify a manufacturer's ability to extract rent from retailers. When service effectiveness is high, a price floor can increase rent available for extraction by raising service. Resolving the manufacturer's service-provision/rent-extraction tradeoff drives the optimal pricing strategy – which sometimes entails not using RPM.

While the academic literature has largely focused on price floors, price ceilings have drawn less academic attention. An exception is Blair and Lafontaine (1999), who highlight the positive impact of RPM ceilings on consumer surplus. Governments also use ceilings, both to control rents (cf., Cheung 1974) and to prevent price gouging on scarce resources (cf., Davis and Kilian 2011). Recent price floors include maternity and children's clothes, light fixtures, women's shoes, dog food, and toys (Pereira, 2008a, Pereira, 2008c).

From a managerial perspective, there are temporal and geographic variations in customer desires for service, and in the legality of RPM, since (a) customers’ service needs change over a product's life cycle; (b) RPM rules change over time; and, (c) RPM rules differ across nations.2 Profit-maximizing managers must adjust their RPM usage in response to changes in product-familiarity that alter the desire for service, and in reactions to temporal and international variations in RPM's legality. Our paper gives insight into RPM's optimal application over a wide range of market conditions, and their consequences for channel members.

We will show that (1) under some – not all – market conditions a manufacturer profits by using RPM; (2) whether a manufacturer is more profitable with an RPM Ceiling, an RPM Floor, or not using RPM depends on how responsive sales are to service as well as customers’ price sensitivity; (3) the floor/ceiling/No-RPM decision is affected by the disparity in retailers’ service effectiveness; (4) the more intense is retailer competition, the greater is the likelihood that a manufacturer will apply RPM – either as a floor or as a ceiling; and, (5) a retailer with service effectiveness that is sufficiently superior to its competitor's effectiveness earns more profit with an RPM Floor than it would in the absence of a floor.

Our analysis shows that when a service-decreasing RPM Ceiling generates more manufacturer profit than would a service-increasing RPM Floor, all retailers are worse off than they would be without a ceiling. Symmetrically, an RPM Floor reduces profit for at least one retailer, and often for both retailers. Moreover, there are market conditions in which a retailer with highly effective service is profit-incented to press for the imposition of an RPM Floor. In sum, the imposition of an RPM rule affects both total channel profit and its distribution among channel members.

We organize the paper as follows. The next Section offers a brief literature review, followed by a Section with our assumptions and demand curve. The ensuing two Sections detail RPM with retailers who are homogeneous, then heterogeneous. The next Section provides answers to the five questions raised above. We then address the robustness of our results; we also list potential research questions by generalizing our demand curve. We end with a discussion and conclusion.

Section snippets

Literature Review

We divide existing models of resale price maintenance (RPM) in the absence of free riding into two research streams. The first looks at pricing decisions; the second examines the interaction between price and a retailer-controlled, non-price variable. The first stream focuses on an RPM price ceiling that lessens markups above cost at all channel levels. The second stream explores the use of RPM price floors to expand retail service. Here we present an overview of these two literature streams,

Assumptions and Demand

Here we state and justify our assumptions; then we construct a demand model that spans a range of retailer differentiation, from homogeneity to any degree of heterogeneity.

RPM Decisions When Retailers are Homogeneous

In this Section we analyze the manufacturer's three pricing rules when retailers are homogeneous. Service disparity is zero since σ1=σ20. We start with No-RPM; this yields a baseline for evaluating the manufacturer's profit gain from applying an RPM Ceiling or an RPM Floor.

RPM Decisions When Retailers are Heterogeneous

In this Section we analyze the manufacturer's pricing rules when retailers are heterogeneous. There is service disparity since σ1>σ20. We start with No-RPM, again obtaining a baseline for evaluating the manufacturer's benefit from an RPM rule. While our basic logic remains the same as in the previous Section, heterogeneity yields a richer understanding of the complexities of inter-retailer competition than can be deduced from a simple homogeneity model.

With heterogeneity, the 1st retailer

Five Questions and their Answers

In the Introduction we raised five questions concerning the impact of RPM's legalization on the members of a distribution channel. For each question we provide a Proposition containing a straightforward answer. Four of the Propositions are accompanied by a Lemma that furnishes a more technical explanation. The answer to Question 1 focuses on homogeneity, while answers to Questions 2–4 deal with heterogeneity. These Questions are followed by a graphical delineation of the portions of parameter

Robustness

An important consideration is the robustness of our results. Our use of linear demand is common in the analytical-channels literature, the same is true for normalizing price sensitivity and the demand intercept to one, as well as setting fixed costs of production and distribution to zero – as stated in Assumption 9. These normalizations have no impact on our results. To show this we re-write retail profit as πi=(piW)[αβp+χpj]+2σisiwsi. The demand intercept is now α, price sensitivity is β,

Discussion and Conclusion

We have derived a manufacturer's optimal pricing strategy when resale price maintenance (RPM) can be used to force retail prices either above (a floor) or below (a ceiling) their equilibrium values when RPM is not employed. Here we summarize theoretical, managerial, legal, and public policy implications of our analyses; we also offer suggestions for future research.

Executive Summary

We derive a manufacturer's optimal use of legally permissible resale price maintenance (RPM) to maximize its own profit when its merchandise is not subject to free riding. RPM allows a manufacturer to compel its retailers to charge prices that are higher, or lower, than retailers would set on their own. Higher prices suppress service-insensitive sales, but augment service, thus enhancing service-sensitive sales. Conversely, lower prices raise demand but reduce service. An optimal pricing

References (41)

  • S. Chan Choi

    Price Competition in a Channel Structure with a Common Retailer

    Marketing Science

    (1991)
  • Lucas W. Davis et al.

    The Allocative Cost of Price Ceilings in the U.S. Residential Market for Natural Gas

    Journal of Political Economy

    (2011)
  • Preyas S. Desai

    Advertising Fees in Business-Format Franchising

    Management Science

    (1997)
  • Ramarao Desiraju et al.

    Managing a Distribution Channel under Asymmetric Information with Performance Requirements

    Management Science

    (1997)
  • European Commission

    Guidelines on Vertical Restraints, Section 411

    (2010)
  • Warren S. Grimes

    “Resale Price Maintenance: A Competitive Assessment,” FTC Workshop on Resale Price Maintenance

    Panel on Anticompetitive Effects. (mimeo)

    (2009)
  • Gregory T. Gundlach et al.

    Free Riding and Resale Price Maintenance: Insights from Marketing Research and Practice

    The Antitrust Bulletin

    (2010)
  • Pamela J. Harbour et al.

    RPM and the Rule of Reason: Ready or Not, Here We Come?

    The Antitrust Bulletin

    (2010)
  • Charles A. Ingene et al.

    Channel Coordination when Retailers Compete

    Marketing Science

    (1995)
  • Charles A. Ingene, et al.

    Bilateral Monopoly, Identical Distributors, and Game-Theoretic Analyses of Distribution Channels

    Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science

    (2007)
  • Cited by (4)

    • Adverse inclusion of asymmetric advertisers in position auctions

      2023, International Journal of Research in Marketing
    • Revisiting the showrooming effect on online and offline retailers: The strategic role of in-store service

      2022, Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services
      Citation Excerpt :

      They find that the more efficiently manufacturers invest in after-sale services, the more willing retailers are to share demand information. Ingene et al. (2020) study the effect of resale price maintenance (RPM) on retailers' service decisions in a duopoly market and find that the adoption of RPM depends on the retailers' service effectiveness and service-effectiveness disparity. Jiang et al. (2020) focus on the physical store's buy-online-and-pickup-in-store (BOPS) channel and analyze the interaction between the retailer's service decision and the manufacturer's channel selection.

    View full text