Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Optimal EITC in the Presence of Cultural Barriers for Labor Market Participation

  • Published:
Journal of Labor Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper I simulate the entrance to the labor market in the presence of cultural barriers that constraint labor market participation of low-income workers. In this case, an optimal EITC depends on social planner’s relative preferences for persistently unemployed and working poor. I check EITC optimality in the short run under different types of social planners - from mild inequality averse to Rawlsian; and different kinds of policy makers – conservative, who favors the Working Poor, and liberal, who tolerates cultural barriers and favors the unemployed. Using simulations, I find that the imposition of an EITC is optimal in all cases, except for a Rawlsian and liberal policy-maker under the unusual case of full compliance to minimum wage. By calibrating the model for Israel, a country with well-documented cultural barriers for labor market participation, I find that the proposed framework will remain relevant in the foreseeable future. In light of these results and of EITC documented advantages, its scare use in developed economies remains an open question that merits further research.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Immervoll, H., H. Kleven, C. T. Kreiner and E. Saez (2004) performed simulations with linear utility of consumption in which labor costs play a significant role.

  2. As I show in the literature survey, cultural barriers are clearly relevant for immigrants. However, in the present context it is so mainly for the second generation born in the foreign country. The topic of desired policy concerning first immigrants’ generation is a crucial policy issue, which is beyond the scope of the present paper.

  3. This assumption is made only for achieving an analytical solution which technically eases the analysis and allows obtaining results without the need for running simulations. The parameters used under this function assure that the solution keeps relevance compared to reality. In section 5 I use an equal CRRA utility function for tax-payers, minimum-wage worker and persistently unemployed; by using simulations I show that the basic results concerning optimal EITC are relevant also in this case.

  4. This function was used in many papers aiming at characterization of re-distribution; among others see Mattos (2008) and Dahan and Strawczynski (2012).

  5. See Piketty, Saez and Stantcheva (2014) and Hendren and Sprung-Keyser (2019).

  6. Such an analysis is presented by Regev and Strawczynski (2019).

  7. Malul and Luski (2009) show that when education is part of individual’s decisions the EITC is not necessarily an optimal tool for young individuals.

  8. In fact, in a dynamic model we would hardly accept that re-distribution occurs in a set-up where individuals do not participate for ever as a consequence of cultural factors. In such a model, we would expect that cultural factors evolve over time – raising the question of optimality in a framework where cultural factors tend to vanish; such a case is analyzed by Regev and Strawczynski (2019).

  9. For a high δ, which represents cultural barriers, the derivative of labor supply with respect to the EITC may be positive or negative depending on the values of the wage and risk aversion. However, since for this case we assume a high δ, the individual with cultural barriers does not participate, and consequently does not receive an EITC.

  10. In the logarithmic case (θ = 1) the income effect of the EITC as shown in the first term of the denominator of 8′ does not exist, because it cancels out with the same term in the numerator. Note that when there are cultural barriers (i.e., δ is high) the EITC will not affect the entrance decision since the term in the numerator of 8′ will be negative. Thus, the omission of the income effect that is related to the EITC subsidy in the logarithmic case is of a minor importance in this analysis.

  11. Income maintenance systems are usually contingent on chronic unemployment. Concerning participation, an appropriate tool would be selective (i.e., mean-tested) child allowances.

  12. As in many re-distributive models I restrict myself to income taxation revenues that are used for transfers to low income individuals. This approach follows Saez (2002), who assumed that intervention is aimed at redistribution.

  13. Note that the situation differs to the usual non-linear optimal income tax problem as presented by Mirrlees (1971): in that context the heterogeneity of wages drives increasing utility with wages (see Stiglitz 1987). In the present context, if we assume the opposite assumption (i.e., that IM is higher than minimum-wage worker’s full-time wage) and if labor causes disutility, then there is a clear incentive not to work; in that case we would have a corner solution where all minimum-wage workers population becomes chronically unemployed, which is not compatible with what we see in reality. Thus, our assumption assures agent monotonicity in terms of utility, fulfilling the incentive compatibility constraint.

  14. This assumption means that basically individuals at persistently unemployed/minimum-wage groups are willing to work; i.e., they are not “lazy” as eventually mentioned in public discussions.

  15. See Gruber and Saez (2002).

  16. This calculation was first done by Samuelov (2016) and presented in Endweld et al. (2017).

  17. Since these groups do not participate we cannot calculate their income maintenance stipend; moreover, for these two groups the child allowances and spouse stipend constitute the relevant alternative for participating at the labor market.

References

  • Antecol H (2000) An examination of cross-country differences in the gender gap in labor force participation rates. Labour Econ 7:409–426

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Apps, Long and Rees (2014) Optimal piecewise linear income taxation. Journal of Public Economic Theory 16(4):523–545

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bastian J, Michelmore K (2018) The long-term impact of the earned income tax credit on children's education and employment outcomes. J Labor Econ 36(4):1127–1163

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bastian J (2020) The effects of the EITC on maternal labor supply. Manuscript, UpJohn Institute for Employment Research

    Google Scholar 

  • Brender A, Strawczynski M (2006) Earned income tax credit in Israel: designing the system to reflect the charateristics of labor supply and poverty. Israel Economic Review 4(1):27–58

    Google Scholar 

  • Brender and Strawczynski (2020) The employment effects of the EITC program in Israel: evidence on the differential effect of family vs. individual-income based designs. Discussion Paper no 2020.01, Research Department, Bank of Israel

  • Dahan M, Strawczynski M (2012) The optimal asymptotic income tax rate. Journal of Public Economic Theory 14(5):737–755

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckstein Z and Lifshitz O (2012), "household interaction and the labor supply of married women", IZA discussion paper 1267, December

  • Eissa N, Kleven C and Kreiner H (2006), "welfare effects of tax reform, and labor supply at the intensive and extensive margins", chapter 4 in Tax Policy and Labor Market Performance, edited by J. Agell and P.B. Sorensen, Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press

  • Endweld M, Achdut L and Strawczynski M (2017), "Poverty, part-time work and EITC", School of Public Policy Working Paper, Hebrew University of Jerusalem (in Hebrew)

  • Evans W, Garthwaite CL (2014) Giving mom a break: the impact of higher EITC payments on maternal health. Am Econ J Econ Pol 6(2):258–290

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernández R and Fogli A (2005), "Culture: an empirical investigation of beliefs, work, and fertility", NBER Working Paper No 11268

  • Ghazal Read J (2004), "Cultural Influences on Immigrant Women's Labor Force Participation: The Arab-American Case", The International Migration Review, Vol. 38, No. 1 (Spring, 2004), 52–77

  • Gruber J, Saez E (2002) The elasticity of taxable income: evidence and implications. J Public Econ 84(2002):1–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hendren N and Sprung-Keyser B (2019), "A unified welfare analysis of government policies", NBER Working Paper No. 26144

  • Heer B (2001) Wealth distribution and optimal inheritance taxation in life-cycle economies with intergenerational transfers. Scand J Econ 103(3):445–465

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoynes H, Miller D, Simon D (2015) Income, the earned income tax credit, and infant health. Am Econ J Econ Pol 79(1):172–211

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoynes H, Patel A (2018) Effective policy for reducing poverty and inequality? The earned income tax credit and the distribution of income. J Hum Resour 53(4):859–890

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Immervoll H, Kleven H, Kreiner CT, Saez E (2004) Welfare reform in European countries: a micro-simulation analysis. CEPR Discussion Paper No 4324

  • Kleven H (2018) "taxation and the extensive margin reconsidered", keynote lecture at the 69th IIPF conference. Tampere, Finland

    Google Scholar 

  • Malul M, Luski I (2009) The optimal policy combination of the minimum wage and the earned income tax credit. The B E Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy 9(1):1–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mattos E (2008) The revealed social welfare function: USA × Brazil. Brazilian Review of Econometrics 28(2):133–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mirrlees JA (1971) An exploration in the theory of optimal income taxation. Review of Economic Studies 38(114):175–208

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neumark D (2016). Inventory of research on economic self-sufficiency. Economic Self-Sufficiency P.R.I. Institute, UCI. https://www.esspri.uci.edu/researchinventory.php

  • Piketty T, Saez E, Stantcheva S (2014) Optimal taxation of top labor incomes: a tale of three Elasticities. American Economic Journal – Economic Policy 6(1):230–271

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Regev E and Strawczynski M (2019), "The optimal long run earned income tax credit", International Journal of Economic Theory, Forthcoming

  • Reimers C (1985) Cultural differences in labor force participation among married women. Am Econ Rev 75(2):251–255

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelov, S. (2016), "raising the EITC in Israel: the impact on different groups", seminar work at Pakam, Hebrew University of Jerusalem (in Hebrew)

  • Stiglitz, J. (1987), "Pareto efficient and optimal taxation and the new welfare economics", in Handbook of Public Economics, Volume2, a.Auerbach and M.Feldstein, eds., pp. 991–1042. Amsterdam: Elsevier North Holland

  • Saez E (2002), Optimal income transfer programs: intensive versus extensive labor supply responses", Q J Econ, 1039-1073

  • Yashiv E, Kasir N (2013) Arab women in the Israeli labor market: characteristics and policy proposals. Israel Economic Review 10(2):1–41

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Thanks to Yoshihiro Takamatsu for a helpful discussion and to participants at the 75th IIPF Conference in Glasgow for useful remarks.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michel Strawczynski.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of Interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

APPENDIX

APPENDIX

Let us now calculate the alternative income IM. For that purpose, we need to know the number of children, since child allowances is the main source for an alternative income in the case of non-participation. Table 7 shows the data.

Based on the number of children we calculate the child allowances as a source of alternative income. Single parents receive mainly the maintenance stipend as stipulated by law. In Table 8 I show the alternative income of the different groups.

These tables provide all the elements for calculating the labor aversion parameter, by applying equation (9)’. Table 2 shows the estimates of the δ-threshold for the different groups.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Strawczynski, M. Optimal EITC in the Presence of Cultural Barriers for Labor Market Participation. J Labor Res 41, 233–259 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12122-020-09303-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12122-020-09303-6

Keywords

JEL Classification Numbers

Navigation