Skip to main content
Log in

Related party transactions, agency problem, and exclusive effects

  • Published:
European Journal of Law and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines the incentives for, and economic impact of related-party transactions (RPTs) by controlling shareholders (CSHs) of corporate groups. We analyze a theory model of RPTs transacted on ‘market terms’ by two affiliate firms in a group, one of which belongs to an upstream and the other to a downstream market. We show that RPTs of this kind, although non-advantageous to the CSH of the group in terms of transfer price, may be abusive in that they serve the interests of the CSH by sacrificing minority shareholders. This is due to the exclusive effects of such RPTs. We show that a CSH has a strong incentive to exclude upstream rivals for his/her own sake rather than the group’s when he/she is allowed to implement such RPTs. The results shed light on regulation of RPTs: distortions of RPTs arise not only from unfair transfer-pricing but also from large transaction volume. This further implies that competition policies regarding the leverage of market power and anti-competitive vertical mergers may be applied to regulate harmful RPTs.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See La Porta (1999) for examples of corporate groups in countries.

  2. See OECD (2012) for recent issues regarding RPTs and policy measures to cope with them in many countries.

  3. According to Lim and Min (2016), in Copperweld (Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 467 U.S. 752 (1984)), the court excluded most RPTs between affiliate firms under common control from antitrust scrutiny under Sect. 1 of the Sherman Act. The purport is that RPTs are, in essence, no different from transactions between the divisions of a single firm.

  4. In Sinclair (Sinclair Oil Corp. v. Levien, 280 A.2d 717 (Del.1971)), the court stated that it applies the fairness standard to tunneling cases. In Weinberger (Weinberger v. UOP, Inc., 457 A.2d 701, 711 (Del. 1983)), the court additionally explained the concept of fairness. It interpreted fairness by two aspects: fair dealing and fair price. Kang (2017) reinterpreted the standard more rigorously in the context of RPTs of good and services.

  5. See the survey included in OECD (2012).

  6. According to OECD (2012), countries “have divided RPTs into those that they consider benign from those that they regard as potentially problematic” and consider RPTs on market terms benign, by and large.

  7. The unique exception is the Monopoly Regulation and Fair Trade Act (MRFTA), or the antitrust law of Korea. In 2013, the Korea Fair Trade Commission (KFTC) introduced Article 23-2, which regulates large size RPTs (called funneling of business) without the transfer-pricing issue. The purport of the article, however, is interpreted as to preclude nation-wide concentration of large corporate groups’ (or Chaebols’) economic power, rather than protecting minority shareholders or market competition.

  8. KFTC reported that, as of 2015, RPTs in the logistics market accounted for 34.3% of total transactions. The proportion in the market for professional services, which includes the advertising market, amounted to 39.0%.

  9. Korean authorities have implemented extensive policy measures to curb RPTs in the advertising market since 2013. The downward trends of \(CR_3\) since 2013, in the right panel of Fig. 1 are interpreted as the outcome of the policy.

  10. Transfer-pricing advantageous to CSHs is not easily found in these markets. The MRFTA includes an article, called the ’Undue Support Clause’, which prohibits RPTs with transfer-pricing significantly advantageous to CSHs. One cannot find cases that were determined unlawful by the article, apart from a handful of exceptions.

  11. Regarding the purpose of RPTs without the transfer pricing issue and/or, potentially, with symmetric ownership structures, there is a strand of studies investigating the incentives of RPTs with market terms, which focuses on tax avoidance. The CSH may want to make a volume of internal transactions to evade taxes through income shifting, when tax rates or other tax-related environments are non-identical across markets. Such transactions may be made with or without distortion of transfer pricing, and may or may not be aligned with the interests of minor shareholders. See Gramlich et al. (2004), Jung et al. (2009), and Choi et al. (2011), for instances.

  12. Jin (2020) also studies the competitive effects of RPTs with market prices. In comparison with Jin (2020), the novelty and contribution of the current paper are clear in many aspects. Among others, Jin (2020) addresses the situation where the upstream affiliate has already monopolized its market. This makes his work differ a lot from the current paper in both analytical outcomes and policy implications. We will discuss more on this in the next section.

  13. Morck et al. (2005) and Khanna and Yafeh (2007) provide comprehensive surveys of literature on this topic.

  14. Shleifer and Vishny (1997) and Berglof and Thadden (1999) also discuss the point that competition may be insufficient to solve the agency problem, and emphasize the role of corporate governance.

  15. For recent research, see Giroud and Mueller (2010), Guadalupe and Pérez-González (2010), Cremers et al. (2008), and Bloom and Van Reenen (2007), among others.

  16. Waller (2011) states: “While a handful of commentators have lamented the lack of a closer organic connection between these two bodies of law [i.e., corporate governance law and antitrust law], most do not even notice.”

  17. Citing Morck et al. (2005), they explain that the view that corporate groups harm competition dates back to the Great Depression era.

  18. Bernheim and Whinston (1990).

  19. Johnson et al. (2000), Bertrand et al. (2002), Friedman et al. (2003), Cheung et al. (2006), Baek et al. (2006), and Atanasov et al. (2011) also review RPT literature comprehensively.

  20. Our model is based on Ordover et al. (1990). However, the focus of our analysis is quite different.

  21. We can also think of firms competing in capacity and then engaging in price competition with capacity constraint, as is in Kreps and Scheinkman (1983).

  22. In Sect. 4.6, we will consider the case wherein the marginal cost of firm 1 is different from those of other upstream firms.

  23. This assumption of identical fixed cost does not change the qualitative results of the analysis as long as each firm’s fixed cost is common knowledge. When firms differ in their fixed costs, in Nash equilibrium, firms survive in the market in the reverse order of fixed costs, and the formula for the equilibrium number of firms is derived in a manner similar to that in this paper.

  24. Article 11-2 of the MRFTA of Korea requires business groups to make a public disclosure in advance when they want to make a substantial amount of RPTs.

  25. In addition, this assumption is employed to comply with the MRFTA which in principle prohibits price-discrimination between RPTs and market-transactions. One may posit an alternative assumption that conforms to this regulation, i.e., an assumption in which firm 1 maximizes its total profit (that is, the sum of residual market profit and profit from RPTs) during the Cournot competition. However, firm 1’s total profit turns out smaller in this alternative than in the assumption above.

  26. This property holds regardless of the demand function specification as long as the marginal cost is constant. To see this, let the inverse demand function be w(Q) and let the equilibrium quantity without RPTs be \(q_j^*\). With RPTs proportional to the quantity demanded at each price, the residual inverse demand function becomes \(w(Q/\eta )\) for some parameter \(\eta \) that depends on s. The Cournot equilibrium condition is then \(w'({\tilde{Q}}/\eta )({\tilde{q}}_j/\eta )+w({\tilde{Q}}/\eta )=c_j\) for all j, which is satisfied with \({\tilde{q}}_j = \eta q_j^*\). This implies that the equilibrium quantity shrinks exactly by \(\eta \) times, leading to the same equilibrium price as that without RPTs. This result holds regardless of the value of \(\eta \) or s.

  27. More often than not, the CSH of a corporate group in reality establishes an upstream affiliate mainly for the purpose of RPTs.

  28. Note that the profit of the downstream firm A in Eq. (3) is not affected by s as long as the number of firms is fixed.

  29. In Eq. (3), the profit of the downstream affiliate A and, hence, CSH’s cash flow from A decreases with \(\theta _A\) in a negligible range in which \(\theta _A\) is very small. Except for the range, it increases \(\theta _A\).

  30. This section benefits from the comments of an anonymous referee. We thank for the helpful discussion he/she provided.

  31. It should be noticed that above discussion, though providing a good insight, is somewhat incomplete because the degree of cost pass-through will also affects the size of RPTs in equilibrium. Unfortunately, our model cannot parameterize fully the tradeoff between consumer harm and agency costs. The full characterization of this issue is left for future research.

  32. These policies include regulations by corporate laws, among others.

  33. Of course, it should be recognized that RPTs can possibly enhance efficiencies for a corporate group and/or the market as a whole. Therefore, it would be necessary to arrange exceptions for such RPTs when considering ex-ante blanket regulations.

  34. In our model, the fixed cost (f) is the only exogenous variable which represents the entry barrier to the market. One can easily see that, when the size of RPTs are fixed at a certain level, the number of upstream firms increases as the fixed cost becomes smaller. This implies that the CSH has weaker incentive for RPTs when the entry barrier (or the fixed cost) is lower since RPTs in this case cannot easily raise the upstream price.

  35. Of course, one should be cautious about the demerits of competition policy. For example, the burden of proof imposed on competition authorities is usually larger in most jurisdictions than that in the private enforcement of corporate law.

References

  • Aghion, P., & Dewatripont, M. (1999). Competition, financial discipline and growth. Review of Economic Studies, 66(4), 825–852.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alchian, A. A. (1950). Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory. The Journal of Political Economy, 58(3), 211–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atanasov, V., Black, B., & Ciccotello, C. (2011). Law and tunneling. The Journal of Corporation Law, 37(1), 1–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baek, J.-S., Kang, J.-K., & Lee, I. (2006). Business groups and tunneling: Evidence from private securities offerings by Korean Chaebols. The Journal of Finance, 61(5), 2415–2449.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berglof, E., & Thadden, E.-L. V. (1999). The changing corporate governance paradigm, implications for transition and development countries. Stockholm: SITE, CEPR and Stockholm School of Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berle, A., & Means, G. (1932). The modern corporation and private property. New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim, B. D., & Whinston, M. D. (1990). Multimarket contact and collusive behavior. The Rand Journal of Economics, 21(1), 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand, M., Mehta, P., & Mullainathan, S. (2002). Ferreting out tunneling: An application to Indian business groups. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(1), 121–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloom, N., & Reenen, J. V. (2007). Measuring and explaining management practices across firms and countries. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(4), 1351–1408.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cestone, G., & Fumagalli, C. (2005). The strategic impact of resource flexibility in business groups. The Rand Journal of Economics, 36(1), 193–214.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheung, Y., Rau, R., & Stouraitis, A. (2006). Tunneling, propping and expropriation: Evidence from connected party transactions in Hong Kong. Journal of Financial Economics, 82(2), 343–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, W., Kho, Y., & Cho, J. (2011). Tunneling, propping and expropriation: Evidence from connected party transactions in Hong Kong. Related Party Transactions and Tax Avoidance, 29, 121–159.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cremers, K. J. M., Nair, V. B., & Peyer, U. (2008). Takeover defense and competition: The role of stakeholders. Journal of Empirical Legal Studies, 5(4), 791–818.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Encaoua, D., & Jacquemin, A. (1982). Organizational efficiency and monopoly power: The case of French industrial groups. European Economic Review, 19(1), 25–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, E., Johnson, S., & Mitton, T. (2003). Propping and tunneling. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(4), 732–750.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giroud, X., & Mueller, H. M. (2010). Does corporate governance matter in competitive industries? Journal of Financial Economics, 95(3), 312–331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gramlich, J. D., Limpaphayom, P., & Ghon, S. (2004). Taxes, keiretsu affiliation, and income shifting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 37(3), 203–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guadalupe, M., & Pérez-González, F. (2010). Competition and private benefits of control. Mimeo.

  • Hart, O. (1983). The market as an incentive mechanism. The Bell Journal of Economics, 14(2), 366–382.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jin, Y. (2020). Exclusionary effects of internal transactions of large business groups. Global Economic Review. https://doi.org/10.1080/1226508X.2020.1745085.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, S., La Porta, R., & de Silanes, F. L. (2000). Tunneling. The American Economic Review, 90(2), 22–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jung, K. Y., Kim, B. Y., & Kim, B. M. (2009). Tax motivated income shifting and Korean business groups (Chaebol). Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 36, 147–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kang, S. Y. (2017). Rethinking self-dealing and the fairness standard: A law and economics framework for internal transactions in corporate groups. Virginia Law & Business Review, 11(1), 95–147.

    Google Scholar 

  • Khanna, T., & Yafeh, Y. (2007). Business groups in emerging markets: Paragons or parasites? Journal of Economic Literature, 45(2), 331–372.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kreps, D., & Scheinkman, J. (1983). Quantity precommitment and bertrand competition yields cournot outcomes. Bell Journal of Economics, 14, 326–337.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (1999). Corporate ownership around the world. The Journal of Finance, 54(2), 471–517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy, N., Spiegel, Y., & Gilo, D. (2018). Quantity precommitment and bertrand competition yields cournot outcomes. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 10(1), 132–180.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lim, Y., & Min, G. (2016). Competition and corporate governance: Teaming up to police tunneling. Northwestern Journal of International Law & Business, 36(2), 267–301.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morck, R., Wolfenzon, D., & Yeung, B. (2005). Corporate governance, economic entrenchment, and growth. Journal of Economic Literature, 43(3), 655–720.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nalebuff, B., & Stiglitz, J. (1983). Prices and incentives, towards a general theory of compensation and competition. The Bell Journal of Economics, 14(1), 21–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • NRC. (2019). A study for comprehensive reform of the monopoly regulation and fair trade act to meet environment change. Cooperative Research Series 19-12-01, National Research Council for Economics, Humanities and Social Sciences (NCR).

  • OECD. (2012). Related party transactions and minority shareholder rights. Paris: OECD Publishing. https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264168008-en.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ordover, J. A., Saloner, G., & Salop, S. C. (1990). Equilibrium vertical foreclosure. The American Economic Review, 80(1), 127–142.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scharfstein, D. (1988). Product market competition and managerial slack. The Rand Journal of Economics, 19(1), 147–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt, K. (1997). Managerial incentives and product market competition. The Rand Journal of Economics, 64(2), 191–213.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1997). A survey of corporate governance. The Journal of Finance, 52(2), 737–783.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1958). The economics of scale. The Journal of Law and Economics, 1(1), 54–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waller, S. P. (2011). Corporate governance and competition policy. George Mason Law Review, 18(4), 833–887.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weinstein, D. E., & Yafeh, Y. (1995). Japan’s corporate groups: Collusive or competitive? An empirical investigation of Keiretsu behavior. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 43(4), 359–376.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yoon, K. (2018). Market competition and internal transactions in corporate groups. Korean Journal of Law and Economics, 15(1), 81–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank for the helpful discussion with the participants at various seminars including the 2019 Summer Conference of the Korea Academic Society of Industrial Organization. This work was supported by the Sungshin University Research Grant of 2017.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yangsoo Jin.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof of Proposition 2

Proof

Since the sign of the effect of s on \(\Pi _A\) is trivial, it suffices to show that \(\Pi _E\) is increasing in s. Suppose first that s is the interior point of an interval I(N). Then, \({\hat{N}}(s)\) is fixed and \(\Pi _E\) is differentiable near s. Letting \({\hat{N}}(s)=N_0\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi _1}{\partial s}&= \frac{(a-c)^2}{(N_0+1)^2}\cdot \left( -\lambda _A+\lambda _A N_0\right) >0 \end{aligned}$$

Now, suppose that s is at the left end of an interval \({\hat{N}}(s)=N_0\). Then, for sufficiently small \(\epsilon >0\), noting that \(\Lambda \) is continuous in s and \(N_0 \ge {\underline{N}}\ge 2\),

$$\begin{aligned}&\Pi _1(s+\epsilon , {\hat{N}}(s+\epsilon ))-\Pi _1(s, {\hat{N}}(s))\\&\quad = \Pi _1(s+\epsilon , N_0-1)-\Pi _1(s, N_0)\\&\quad =(a-c)^2\left[ \frac{\Lambda (s+\epsilon )+\lambda _A(s+\epsilon )(N_0-1)}{N_0^2}-\frac{\Lambda (s)+\lambda _AsN_0}{(N_0+1)^2}\right] \\&\quad \rightarrow (a-c)^2\left[ \frac{\Lambda (2N_0+1)}{N_0^2(N_0+1)^2}+\frac{\lambda _As(N_0^2-N_0-1)}{N_0^2(N_0+1)^2}\right] \\&\quad >0 \end{aligned}$$

as \(\epsilon \) approaches to zero, which completes the proof. \(\square \)

1.2 Proof of Proposition 3

Proof

The function \(\Gamma /(\lambda _A+\lambda _B)\) can be rewritten as

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\Gamma }{\lambda _A+\lambda _B}&=\frac{\lambda _A^2}{(1+\theta _A)(\lambda _A+\lambda _B)}\\&=\frac{(2+2\theta _B +\theta _A)^2}{\left( 4+5\theta _A+5\theta _B+4\theta _A\theta _B+\theta _A^2 +\theta _B^2\right) \left( 4+4\theta _A+4\theta _B+3\theta _A\theta _B\right) }, \end{aligned}$$

which decreases in \((\theta _A, \theta _B)\) unless \(\theta _B\) is near zero. Thus, it has a global maximum less than 1/4 near the origin. Then, we have

$$\begin{aligned}\frac{\sigma \Gamma }{\lambda _A+\lambda _B}<\frac{1}{4} \Leftrightarrow (2N^2+4N+1) \sigma \Gamma -(N^2 +N-1)(\lambda _A +\lambda _B)<0,\end{aligned}$$

which in turn implies \(\Psi <0\) for all N. \(\square \)

1.3 Proof of Lemma 4

Proof

In the upstream market, with the inverse residual demand in equation (4) and given the number of firm N, the upstream firm \(i=2, 3, \ldots , N\) maximizes the following operating profit:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _i (q_{i}, Q_{-i}) = \left( a- c-\frac{Q}{\Lambda }\right) q_i. \end{aligned}$$
(18)

The first order condition gives the following implicit best response functions:

$$\begin{aligned} a-c-\frac{Q_{-i} +2q_i}{\Lambda } = 0, \end{aligned}$$
(19)

for all \(i = 2, \ldots , N\). By the same token, for the upstream affiliate of the group, firm 1, we have the following implicit best response function:

$$\begin{aligned} a -c_1 -\frac{Q_{-1} +2q_1}{\Lambda } = 0. \end{aligned}$$
(20)

Solving the simultaneous equations, the equilibrium quantity and price are

$$\begin{aligned} {\hat{Q}} = \frac{\Lambda (Na-(N-1)c-c_1)}{N+1}=\frac{\Lambda (Na-Nc-\Delta )}{N+1}, \end{aligned}$$
(21)
$$\begin{aligned} {\hat{w}} = \frac{a+(N-1)c +c_1}{N+1}=\frac{a+Nc +\Delta }{N+1}. \end{aligned}$$
(22)

Then, in equilibrium, the quantity produced by each upstream firm is as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} {\hat{q}}_i = \frac{\Lambda (a-2c+c_1)}{N+1}=\frac{\Lambda (a-c +\Delta )}{N+1},\;\;\;\; i= 2, \ldots , N \end{aligned}$$
(23)
$$\begin{aligned} {\hat{q}}_1 = \frac{\Lambda (a+(N-1)c-Nc_1)}{N+1} = \frac{\Lambda (a-c-N\Delta )}{N+1}. \end{aligned}$$
(24)

Now, the equilibrium output by each firm (\({\hat{q}}_i\)), the market output (\({\hat{Q}}\)), and the equilibrium price (\({\hat{w}}\)) are given by

$$\begin{aligned} {\hat{q}}_i = {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll}\frac{\Lambda (a-c +\Delta )}{N+1}, &{} \text {if}\;\; i= 2, \ldots , N\\ \frac{\Lambda (a-c -N\Delta )}{N+1}, &{} \text {if}\;\; i=1, \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(25)
$$\begin{aligned} {\hat{Q}} = \frac{\Lambda (Na-Nc -\Delta )}{N+1}, \end{aligned}$$
(26)
$$\begin{aligned} {\hat{w}} = \frac{a+Nc +\Delta }{N+1}, \end{aligned}$$
(27)

In equilibrium, the operating profit from market transaction of the affiliate and non-affiliates are, respectively

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _i = ({\hat{w}} -c)q_i=\frac{\Lambda \left( a-c +\Delta \right) ^2}{(N+1)^2},\;\;\;\; i= 2, \ldots , N \end{aligned}$$
(28)
$$\begin{aligned} \pi _1^{MKT} = ({\hat{w}}-c_1)q_1=\frac{\Lambda \left( a-c-N\Delta \right) ^2}{(N+1)^2} \end{aligned}$$
(29)

For the entrant, there is an additional operating profit from RPTs, which is

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _1^{RPT} = ({\hat{w}}-c_1)sq_A =\frac{\lambda _A (a-c-N\Delta )(Na-Nc -\Delta )s}{(N+1)^2} \end{aligned}$$
(30)

The Nash equilibrium number of firms, \({\hat{N}}\), is determined by the following inequalities.

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\Lambda \left( a-c +\Delta \right) ^2}{({\hat{N}}+2)^2} < f \le \frac{\Lambda \left( a-c +\Delta \right) ^2}{({\tilde{N}}+1)^2} \end{aligned}$$
(31)

or

$$\begin{aligned} ({\hat{N}}+1)^2 \le \frac{\Lambda \left( a-c +\Delta \right) ^2}{f}< ({\hat{N}}+2)^2. \end{aligned}$$
(32)

\(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Yoon, KS., Jin, Y. Related party transactions, agency problem, and exclusive effects. Eur J Law Econ 51, 1–30 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-020-09680-4

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-020-09680-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation