Skip to content
Licensed Unlicensed Requires Authentication Published by De Gruyter February 1, 2020

Pretrial Beliefs and Verdict Accuracy: Costly Juror Effort and Free Riding

  • Brishti Guha EMAIL logo

Abstract

If jurors care about reaching the correct verdict, but also experience costs to paying attention during the trial, even a small effort cost generates interesting interactions between pretrial beliefs and verdict accuracy. I demonstrate the existence of a strong free riding effect; jurors respond to a more informative prior by reducing their probabilities of paying attention, to the extent that over a non-empty range, a more informative prior will be associated with poorer verdicts. Pretrial beliefs can depend on several factors: I consider two – the extent of discovery during the pre-plea bargaining process, and the efficiency of the police. My results imply that more liberal discovery rules, which result in a less noisy plea bargaining process, will actually be complemented by greater juror effort over a range, resulting in more accurate verdicts. In contrast, greater police efficiency will, over a range, elicit a sufficient drop in juror effort such that verdicts are less accurate. Thus, improving discovery has added benefits over a range, while the benefits of exogenous improvements in policing may be dampened. I briefly extend the model to cases where attentive jurors receive an imperfect public signal instead of a perfect one, and to cases where jurors’ utilities from convicting a guilty defendant differ from their utilities from acquitting an innocent one.

Acknowledgements

I thank the Editor in Chief and three anonymous referees.

References

Austen-Smith, D., and J. S. Banks. 1996. “Information Aggregation, Rationality, and the Condorcet Jury Theorem.” American Political Science Review 90: 34–45.10.2307/2082796Search in Google Scholar

Baker, S., and C. Mezetti. 2001. “Prosecutorial Resources, Plea Bargaining, and the Decision to Go to Trial.” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 17: 149–67.10.1093/jleo/17.1.149Search in Google Scholar

Bjerk, D. 2007. “Guilt Shall Not Escape or Innocence Suffer? The Limits of Plea Bargaining When Defendant Guilt Is Uncertain.” American Law and Economics Review 9: 305–29.10.1093/aler/ahm010Search in Google Scholar

Cai, H. 2009. “Costly Participation and Heterogeneous Preferences in Informational Committees.” RAND Journal of Economics 40: 173–89.10.1111/j.1756-2171.2008.00060.xSearch in Google Scholar

Coughlan, P. J. 2000. “In Defense of Unanimous Jury Verdicts: Mistrials, Communication and Strategic Voting.” American Political Science Review 94: 375–93.10.2307/2586018Search in Google Scholar

Farmer, A., and P. Pecorino. 2002. “Pretrial Bargaining with Self-serving Bias and Asymmetric Information.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 48: 163–76.10.1016/S0167-2681(01)00236-0Search in Google Scholar

Feddersen, T., and W. Pesendorfer. 1998. “Convicting the Innocent: The Inferiority of Unanimous Jury Verdicts under Strategic Voting.” American Political Science Review 92: 23–35.10.2307/2585926Search in Google Scholar

Feddersen, T., and A. Sandroni. 2006. “Ethical Voters and Costly Information Acquisition.” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 1: 287–311.10.1561/100.00000011Search in Google Scholar

Friedman, E., and A. L. Wickelgren. 2005. “Bayesian Juries and the Limits to Deterrence.” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 22: 70–86.10.1093/jleo/ewj007Search in Google Scholar

Gerardi, D., and L. Yariv. 2008. “Information Acquisition in Committees.” Games and Economic Behavior 62: 436–59.10.1016/j.geb.2007.06.007Search in Google Scholar

Gershkov, A., and B. Szentes. 2009. “Optimal Voting Schemes with Costly Information Acquisition.” Journal of Economic Theory 144: 36–68.10.1016/j.jet.2008.02.004Search in Google Scholar

Guha, B. 2015. ““inferiority” Complex? Policing, Private Precautions and Crime.” European Journal of Law and Economics 39: 97–106.10.1007/s10657-013-9408-xSearch in Google Scholar

Guha, B. 2018. “Secret Ballots and Costly Information Gathering: The Jury Size Problem Revisited.” International Review of Law and Economics 54: 58–67.10.1016/j.irle.2017.10.005Search in Google Scholar

Guha, B. 2020. “Should Jurors Deliberate?” Review of Law and Economics, forthcoming.10.1515/rle-2018-0011Search in Google Scholar

Helland, E., and Y. Raviv. 2008. “The Optimal Jury Size When Jury Deliberation Follows a Random Walk.” Public Choice 134: 255–62.10.1007/s11127-007-9222-5Search in Google Scholar

Hummel, P. 2012. “Deliberation in Large Juries with Diverse Preferences.” Public Choice 150: 595–608.10.1007/s11127-010-9718-2Search in Google Scholar

Koriyama, Y., and B. Szentes. 2009. “A Resurrection of the Condorcet Jury Theorem.” Theoretical Economics 4: 227–52.Search in Google Scholar

Li, H. 2001. “A Theory of Conservatism.” Journal of Political Economy 109: 617–36.10.1086/321018Search in Google Scholar

Martinelli, C. 2006. “Would Rational Voters Acquire Costly Information?” Journal of Economic Theory 129: 225–51.10.1016/j.jet.2005.02.005Search in Google Scholar

Martinelli, C. 2007. “Rational Ignorance and Voting Behavior.” International Journal of Game Theory 35: 315–35.10.1007/s00182-006-0051-4Search in Google Scholar

McCannon, B. 2011. “Strategic Offsetting Behavior: Evidence from National Collegiate Athletic Association Men’s Basketball.” Contemporary Economic Policy 29: 550–63.10.1111/j.1465-7287.2010.00243.xSearch in Google Scholar

McCannon, B., and P. Walker. 2016. “Endogenous Competence and a Limit to the Condorcet Jury Theorem.” No (16-12). Department of Economics, West Virginia University.10.1007/s11127-016-0366-zSearch in Google Scholar

Mukhopadhyaya, K. 2003. “Jury Size and the Free Rider Problem.” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 19: 24–44.10.1093/jleo/19.1.24Search in Google Scholar

Oliveros, S. 2013. “Abstention, Ideology and Information Acquisition.” Journal of Economic Theory 148: 871–902.10.1016/j.jet.2012.10.006Search in Google Scholar

Peltzman, S. 1975. “The Effects of Automobile Safety Regulation.” Journal of Political Economy 83: 677–725.10.1086/260352Search in Google Scholar

Persico, N. 2004. “Committee Design with Endogenous Information.” Review of Economic Studies 71: 165–91.10.1111/0034-6527.00280Search in Google Scholar

Priest, G. L., and B. Klein. 1984. “The Selection of Disputes for Litigation.” Journal of Legal Studies 13: 1–55.10.1086/467732Search in Google Scholar

Reinganum, J. F. 1988. “Plea Bargaining and Prosecutorial Discretion.” American Economic Review 78: 713–28.Search in Google Scholar

Reinganum, J. F., and L. L. Wilde. 1986. “Settlement, Litigation, and the Allocation of Litigation Costs.” RAND Journal of Economics 17: 557–66.10.2307/2555481Search in Google Scholar

Thaman, S. C. 2007. “Plea-bargaining, Negotiating Confessions and Consensual Resolution of Criminal Cases.” SSRN working paper.Search in Google Scholar

Triossi, M. 2013. “Costly Information Acquisition: Is It Better to Toss a Coin?” Games and Economic Behavior 82: 169–91.10.1016/j.geb.2013.07.008Search in Google Scholar

Turner, J. I. 2017. “Plea Bargaining.” SSRN working paper.10.4337/9780857939586.00009Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2020-02-01

© 2020 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 20.4.2024 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2018-0020/html
Scroll to top button