Skip to content
Licensed Unlicensed Requires Authentication Published by De Gruyter February 26, 2020

Fiat Money as a Public Signal, Medium of Exchange, and Punishment

  • Pedro Gomis-Porqueras EMAIL logo and Ching-Jen Sun

Abstract

This paper studies different welfare-enhancing roles that fiat money can have. To do so, we consider an indivisible monetary framework where agents are randomly and bilaterally matched, while the government has weak enforcement powers. Within this environment, we analyze state contingent monetary policies and characterize the resulting equilibria under different government record-keeping technologies. We show that a threat of injecting fiat money, conditional on private actions, can improve allocations and achieve efficiency. This type of state contingent policy is effective even when the government cannot observe any private trades and agents can only communicate with the government through cheap talk. In all these equilibria fiat money and self-enforcing credit are complements in the off equilibrium. Finally, this type of equilibria can also emerge even when the injection of fiat money is not a public signal.

JEL Classification: E00; E40; C73; D82

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank the Editor and the anonymous referees for their suggestions and feedback. We also like to thank Luis Araujo, Andrei Shevchenko, Aleks Berentsen, Sebastian Lotz, Fernando Martin, Raoul Minetti, Cyril Monnet and Chris Waller for their comments.

Appendix

A Proof of Proposition 1

First we observe that on the equilibrium path (where agents follow unconditional gift-giving), the expected payoff for each agent is

VG=σ+δ1β(uc).

Once the government sees a deviation, M units of money are randomly injected into the economy. Let VM0 denote the expected payoff of an agent without money and VM1 the expected payoff of an agent with money. Following Kiyotaki and Wright (1989), we have

VM0=βVM0+σMN1[c+β(VM1VM0)]+δ(uc)=σMN1[c+β(VM1VM0)]+δ(uc)1β,and
VM1=βVM1+σNMN1[u+β(VM0VM1)]+δ(uc)=σNMN1[u+β(VM0VM1)]+δ(uc)1β.

The expected payoff for an agent who deviates is given by

Vd=MNVM1+NMNVM0=MNσNMN1[u+β(VM0VM1)]+δ(uc)1β+NMNσMN1[c+β(VM1VM0)]+δ(uc)1β=σM(NM)N(N1)+δ1β(uc).

Hence no agent will deviate from gift-giving if c+βVGβVd, which implies that the discount rate has to satisfy

βcc+σ(1M(NM)N(N1))(uc).

On the other hand, after a deviation, in order for agents to follow a monetary equilibrium, we require ββMcc+σNMN1(uc) as derived in Kiyotaki and Wright (1989). The two inequalities hold simultaneously if

βcc+σmin{1M(NM)N(N1),NMN1}(uc)=βPO.

B Proof of Proposition 2

In order to show that the strategy profile supports gift exchange as an equilibrium, we need to establish the following two conditions:

I. No agent has an incentive to deviate on the equilibrium path

There are two conditions to be established:

(i) As agents follow unconditional gift-giving on the equilibrium path, the expected payoff for each agent is

VG=σ+δ1β(uc).

Pick any matched pair (i, mt(i)) in period t, and suppose (without loss of generality) that mt(i) likes i's good. If agent i follows the equilibrium path and produces for mt(i), his expected payoff is

c+βVG.

If i deviates from the equilibrium path and does not produce for mt(i), both i and mt(i) will report to the central bank. The central bank then hands out one unit of money to both i and mt(i). Following the monetary equilibrium after deviation, i's expected payoff is VM=21. Accordingly, i has no incentive to deviate whenever we satisfy

c+βVGβVM=21.

First we derive VM=21 explicitly. Again, following Kiyotaki and Wright (1989), VM=20 and VM=21 satisfy the following system of equations:

[1β+2σβN1σ2N1βσβN2N11β+σβN2N1][VM=20VM=21]=[δ(uc)σ2N1cδ(uc)+σN2N1u]

Accordingly, VM=21 can be solved as

VM,2=(1β+2σβN1)(δ(uc)+σN2N1u)+σβN2N1(δ(uc)σ2N1c)(1β+2σβN1)(1β+σβN2N1)σ2β22(N2)(N1)2=(uc)[δ(1β+σβNN1)+2σ2β(N2)(N1)2]+(1β)σuN2N1(1β)(1β+σβNN1)

Hence the no-deviation condition becomes

c+βσ1β(uc)β1β(uc)2σ2β(N2)(N1)2+(1β)σuN2N11β+σβNN1,

which can be rearranged as:

(uc)βσ(1β)cβσN2N1(uc)2σβN1+(1β)u1β+σβNN10.

This inequality holds if

(uc)βσ(1β)cβσ(uc)2σβN1+(1β)u1β+σβ0.

After some simplifications, we get the following quadratic inequality in β:

[c(2σ1)+σ2(uc)(12N1)]β2+2c(1σ)βc0.

Let σ* denote the unique σ ∈ (0, 1) such that c(2σ1)+σ2(uc)(12N1)=0. The coefficient of β2

c(2σ1)+σ2(uc)(12N1){>0σ>σ=0σ=σ<0σ<σ.

Consider N > 3 and let β1 denote the smallest value of β ∈ (0, 1) that satisfies the above quadratic inequality. It can be readily verified that

β1={2c(1σ)+(2c(1σ))2+4c[c(2σ1)+σ2(uc)(12N1)]2[c(2σ1)+σ2(uc)(12N1)]σσ12(1σ)σ=σ.

(ii) When seeing no deviations, an agent has no incentive to unilaterally deviate from the equilibrium path and report to the central bank. This requires

VM=11VG.

Recall that

c+βVM=11βVM=10,and VM=11=σN1N1[u+β(VM=10VM=11)]+δ(uc)1β.

Therefore the above inequality holds as

VM=11=σN1N1[u+β(VM=10VM=11)]+δ(uc)1βσ+δ1β(uc)=VG.

II. No agent has an incentive to deviate off the equilibrium path

There are two conditions to be established:

(i) Since the government can not observe the actions of private agents, it is important to determine whether agents have been provided proper incentives to report a deviation. To determine when that will be the case, we need to establish, for any given matched pair, it is optimal for both agents to report to the central bank after seeing a deviation. We note that after seeing a deviation from his trading partner, an agent must believe that his trading partner is the only one who deviates. The following condition makes sure that each agent in a matched pair will report to the central bank after seeing a deviation:

VM=21VM=10.

When there is only one unit of money in the economy, we have the following system of equations on VM=10 and VM=11:

[1β+σβN1σ1N1βσβ1β+σβ][VM=10VM=11]=[δ(uc)σ1N1cδ(uc)+σu]

Hence VM=10 can be solved as

VM=10=(δ(uc)σ1N1c)(1β+σβ)+(δ(uc)+σu)σ1N1β(1β+σβN1)(1β+σβ)σ2β2N1.

The no-deviation inequality becomes

(uc)[δ(1β+σβNN1)+2σ2β(N2)(N1)2]+(1β)σuN2N1(1β)(1β+σβNN1)(δ(uc)σ1N1c)(1β+σβ)+(δ(uc)+σu)σ1N1β(1β+σβN1)(1β+σβ)σ2β2N1

As (1β)(1β+σβNN1)=(1β+σβN1)(1β+σβ)σ2β2N1, the inequality holds if and only if

(uc)[δ(1β+σβNN1)+2σ2β(N2)(N1)2]+(1β)σuN2N1(δ(uc)σ1N1c)(1β+σβ)+(δ(uc)+σu)σ1N1β.

After some simplifications, we get

βu(N2)+cu(N2)+c+σ(uc)(2N11)β2.

Observe that β2>1 when N > 3. Hence this condition holds for all β ∈ (0, 1) whenever N > 3.

(ii) If someone deviates in a bilateral meeting, both agents will report to the central bank, and two units of money will be injected into the economy. We need to make sure that agents follow a monetary equilibrium after money injection, which requires

ββM=2=cc+σN2N1(uc).

Now, combining all conditions in I and II, we conclude that there exists an equilibrium where a threat of money injection can support gift-giving when N > 3 and

ββCTmax{β1,βM=2}.

Note that limNβ1<1 and limNβM=2<1 thus we have that limNβCT<1.

C Proof of Proposition 3

(i) Recall that

βM=cc+σNMN1(uc)βPO=cc+σmin{1M(NM)N(N1),NMN1}(uc)

Apparently βMβPO. For βPO=βM, we require

1M(NM)N(N1)NMN1

A simplification shows that the above inequality holds if and only if MN.

(ii) Recall that

β1={2c(1σ)+(2c(1σ))2+4c[c(2σ1)+σ2(uc)(12N1)]2[c(2σ1)+σ2(uc)(12N1)]σσ12(1σ)σ=σ,

where σ* is the unique σ ∈ (0, 1) that solves c(2σ1)+σ2(uc)(12N1)=0, and

βCT=max{β1,βM=2}.

As βMβM=2 for any M ≥ 2, βMβCT if βMβ1. Given σ12,σσ* as c(2σ1)+σ2(uc)(12N1)c(2121)+(12)2(uc)(12N1)=(12)2(uc)(12N1)>0. Accordingly,

β1=2c(1σ)+(2c(1σ))2+4c[c(2σ1)+σ2(uc)(12N1)]2[c(2σ1)+σ2(uc)(12N1)].

Define

a=c(2σ1)+σ2(uc)(12N1)andb=2c(1σ).

Then

β1=b+b2+4ac2a

and βMβ1 if

cc+σNMN1(uc)b+b2+4ac2ab2+4acb+2acc+σNMN1(uc)

which can be further simplified to

(NM)2N1(uc)+2c(NM)c(N3)0.

Accordingly, βMβCT if

MN(N1)c2+ucN1c(N3)cuc.

References

Andolfatto, D. 2010. “Essential Interest-bearing Money.” Journal of Economic Theory 145: 1495–1507.10.20955/wp.2009.044Search in Google Scholar

Alvarez, F., and U. Jermann. 2000. “Efficiency, Equilibrium, and Asset Pricing with Risk of Default.” Econometrica 68 (4): 775–98.10.1111/1468-0262.00137Search in Google Scholar

Araujo, L. 2004. “Social Norms and Money.” Journal of Monetary Economics 51: 241–56.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2003.01.005Search in Google Scholar

Araujo, L., and B. Camargo. 2015. “Limited Monitoring and the Essentiality of Money.” Journal of Mathematical Economics 58: 32–37.10.1016/j.jmateco.2015.03.004Search in Google Scholar

Araujo, L., and T-W. Hu. 2018. “Optimal Monetary Interventions in Credit Markets.” Journal of Economic Theory 178: 455–87.10.1016/j.jet.2018.10.005Search in Google Scholar

Aruoba, B., G. Rocheteau, and C. Waller. 2007. “Bargaining and the Value of Money.” Journal of Monetary Economics 54: 2636–55.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2007.07.003Search in Google Scholar

Awaya, Y., and H. Fukai. 2015. “Essentiality-of-Money Is Delicate.” working paper.Search in Google Scholar

Bernanke, B. 2015. The Courage to Act: A Memoir of a Crisis and Its Aftermath. New York, United States: WW Norton & Co.Search in Google Scholar

Chari, V., L. Christiano, and P. Kehoe. 1996. “Optimality of the Friedman Rule in Economies with Distorting Taxes.” Journal of Monetary Economics 37: 203–23.10.3386/w4443Search in Google Scholar

Cipolla, C. 1956. Money, Prices, and Civilization in the Mediterranean World: Fifth to Seventeenth Century. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Dubey, P., J. Geanakoplos, and M. Shubik. 2005. “Default and Punishment in General Equilibrium.” Econometrica 73 (1): 1–37.10.1111/j.1468-0262.2005.00563.xSearch in Google Scholar

Einaudi, L. 1937. “The Medieval Practice of Managed Currency.” In The Lessons of Monetary Experience: Essays in Honor of Irving Fisher, edited by Arthur D. Gayer, 259–68. New York: Farrar and Reinehart.Search in Google Scholar

Einaudi, L. 1953. “The Theory of Imaginary Money from Charlemagne to the French Revolution.” In Chapter 14 of Enterprise and Secular Change: Readings in Economic History, edited by Frederic C. Lane and Jelle C. Riemersma. Homewood: Richard D. Irwin.Search in Google Scholar

Friedman, M. 1969. The Optimum Quantity of Money and Other Essays. Chicago: Aldine Publishing Company.Search in Google Scholar

Gomis-Porqueras, P., and A. Peralta-Alva. 2010. “Optimal Monetary and Fiscal Polices in a Search Theoretic Model of Monetary Exchange.” European Economic Review 54: 331–44.10.1016/j.euroecorev.2009.08.007Search in Google Scholar

Gomis-Porqueras, P., and D. Sanches. 2013. “Optimal Monetary Policy in a Model of Money and Credit.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 45: 701–30.10.1111/jmcb.12021Search in Google Scholar

Gu, C., F. Mattesini, and R. Wright. 2016. “Money and Credit Redux.” Econometrica 84: 1–32.10.3982/ECTA12798Search in Google Scholar

Harsanyi, J., and R. Selten. 1988. A General Theory of Equilibrium Selection in Games. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Search in Google Scholar

Hayek, F. 1945. “The Use of Knowledge in Society.” American Economic Review 35: 519–30.Search in Google Scholar

Hu, T-W, J. Kennan, and N. Wallace. 2009. “Coalition-Proof Trade and the Friedman Rule in the Lagos-Wright Model.” Journal of Political Economy 117: 116–37.10.3386/w13310Search in Google Scholar

Kandori, M. 1992. “Social Norms and Community Enforcement.” Review of Economic Studies 59: 63–80.10.2307/2297925Search in Google Scholar

Kehoe, T., and D. Levine. 1993. “Debt-Constrained Asset Markets.” Review of Economic Studies 60 (4): 865–88.10.2307/2298103Search in Google Scholar

Kiyotaki, N., and R. Wright. 1989. “On Money as a Medium of Exchange.” Journal of Political Economy 97: 927–54.10.1086/261634Search in Google Scholar

Kiyotaki, N., and R. Wright. 1991. “A Contribution to the Pure Theory of Money.” Journal of Economic Theory 53: 215–35.10.1016/0022-0531(91)90154-VSearch in Google Scholar

Kiyotaki, N., and R. Wright. 1993. “A Search-Theoretic Approach to Monetary Economics.” American Economic Review 83: 63–77.Search in Google Scholar

Kindleberger, C. 1993. A Financial History of Western Europe, 2nd ed. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Kocherlakota, N. 1998. “Money is Memory.” Journal of Economic Theory 81: 232–51.10.1006/jeth.1997.2357Search in Google Scholar

Lagos, R., and R. Wright. 2005. “A Unified Framework for Monetary Theory and Policy Analysis.” Journal of Political Economy 113: 463–84.10.26509/frbc-wp-200211Search in Google Scholar

Lotz, S., and C. Zhang. 2016. “Money and Credit as Means of Payment: A New Monetarist Approach.” Journal of Economic Theory 164: 68–100.10.1016/j.jet.2015.08.003Search in Google Scholar

Nosal, E., and G. Rocheteau. 2011. Money, Payments and Liquidity. Cambridge: MIT Press.10.7551/mitpress/9780262016285.001.0001Search in Google Scholar

Sargent, Thomas J., and Francois R. Velde. 2002. The Big Problem of Small Change. Princeton: Princeton University Press.10.1515/9781400851621Search in Google Scholar

Spufford, P. 1988. Money and its Use in Medieval Europe. Cambridge: Cam- bridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511583544Search in Google Scholar

Takahashi, S. 2010. “Community Enforcement when Players Observe Partners’ Past Play.” Journal of Economic Theory 145: 42–62.10.1016/j.jet.2009.06.003Search in Google Scholar

Wiseman, T. 2015. “A Note on the Essentiality of Money Under Limited Memory.” Review of Economic Dynamics 18: 881–93.10.1016/j.red.2015.09.001Search in Google Scholar

Williamson, S., and R. Wright. 2010a. “New Monetarist Economics: Methods.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 92: 265–302.10.20955/r.92.265-302Search in Google Scholar

Williamson, S., and R. Wright. 2010b. “New Monetarist Economics: Models.” In Handbook of Monetary Economics, edited by B. Friedman, and M. Woodford. Amsterdam: Elsevier.10.1016/B978-0-444-53238-1.00002-8Search in Google Scholar

Woodford, M. 1990. “The Optimum Quantity of Money.” In Handbook of Monetary Economics, vol. 2, edited by B. Friedman and F.H. Hahn. Amsterdam: North-Holland.10.1016/S1573-4498(05)80027-XSearch in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2020-02-26

© 2020 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 14.5.2024 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2019-0098/html
Scroll to top button