Skip to content
Licensed Unlicensed Requires Authentication Published by De Gruyter December 12, 2019

Animal spirits in an open economy: an interaction-based approach to the business cycle

  • Tae-Seok Jang EMAIL logo

Abstract

This paper examines the effects of boundedly rational expectation on the business cycle in a two-country New Keynesian model. Forecast heuristics in a closed-economy, De Grauwe’s (2011) model, is extended, and the effects of heterogeneous agents are incorporated in an open economy. In particular, the expectation formation process is constrained by waves of optimists and pessimists – the so-called “animal spirits.” As a result, the model is able to explain group behavior based on forecast performance, which has significant effects on output and inflation dynamics in the two countries. The simulation results suggest that heterogeneity in group behavior and nominal rigidities, as well as a moderate degree of international trade, amplify spillover effects on international business cycles leading to high cross-correlations in output and inflation.

JEL Classification: C63; E32; F41

Acknowledgement

A preliminary version of this paper was presented at the Econophysics Colloquium 2015 in Prague and the 11th Dynare Conference in Brussels. I would like to thank all the participants for their active involvement in the conferences. In particular, I am grateful for the helpful comments provided by anonymous referees. All remaining errors are mine.

Appendix: Two-country model in canonical form

This section describes in detail the setup of the two-country model. The complete derivation of deep parameters can be found in the literature on standard two-country New Keynesian models (Galí and Monacelli 2005; Da Silveira 2006; Jang and Okano 2015).

xt=Et(xt+1)ω4+1(ω2+1α)σ{rtEt(πt+1)}+α+ω2ω2+1α{Et(xt+1)xt};πt=βEt(πt+1)βασω4+1{Et(xt+1)Et(xt+1)}+ασ(1+β)+κHςω4+1xtσ[α(1+β)κHω2]ω4+1xtασω4+1{xt1xt1}+κHrt;rt=ϕrrt1+(1ϕr)(ϕππt+ϕxxt);xt=Et(xt+1)ω4+1(ω2+1α)σ{rtEt(πt+1)}+α+ω2ω2+1α{Et(xt+1)xt};πt=βEt(πt+1)βασω4+1{Et(xt+1)Et(xt+1)}+ασ(1+β)+κFςω4+1xtσ[α(1+β)κFω2]ω4+1xtασω4+1{xt1xt1}+κFrt;rt=ϕrrt1+(1ϕr)(ϕππt+ϕxxt),

where ω0=2(1α)(ση1), ω2=2α(1α)(ση1) and ω4=4α(1α)(ση1). ς, κH, and κF are defined as (ω2+1)σ+(ω4+1)φ, (1θH)(1θHβ)θH, and (1θF)(1θFβ)θF, respectively.

Table 5:

Calibrated values for animal spirits in a two-country model.

ParametersDescriptionValue
σRisk aversion1.0
ηElasticity of substitution between goods2.0
φLabor disutility20.0
θHCalvo lotteries in country ’s price0.9
θFCalvo lotteries in country ’s price0.75
ϕπTaylor rule inflation in country 1.75
ϕyTaylor rule output growth in country 0.75
ϕrInterest rate smoothing in country 0.5
ϕπTaylor rule inflation in country 1.25
ϕyTaylor rule output growth in country 1.0
ϕrInterest rate smoothing in country 0.5
  1. The discount factor β is set to 0.99. The effect of trade openness on the model is examined using simulations (α = 0.1, 0.9).

Table 5 shows the calibrated values for deep parameters in the model. Concerning price stickiness, Smets and Wouters (2003) estimate the Calvo price in the Euro Area. In their studies, they use the time period 1980:Q2–1999:Q4, and estimate the price indexation parameter as 0.908. This is roughly 2.5 years in quarterly magnitude (110.90810). In their subsequent study, Smets and Wouters (2007) use a US data set for the period 1984:Q4–2004:Q4 (“Great Moderation”), and found that the estimated Calvo price is 0.73. This corresponds to roughly 1 year in quarterly magnitude (i.e. 110.734). Hence, the parameters values used in the paper can be considered to be the case for the Euro Area (country ’ price) and the US economy (country ’ price), respectively.

The parameters are connected to the model coefficients in canonical form as follows:

{κH=(1θH)(1θHβ)/θH;κF=(1θF)(1θFβ)/θF;ω2=2α(1α)(ση1);ω4=4α(1α)(ση1);ς=(ω2+1)σ+(ω4+1)φ;
{a1=(ω4+1)/{(ω2+1α)σ};a2=(α+ω2)/(ω2+1α);b1=(βασ)/(ω4+1);b2={ασ(1+β)+κHς}/(ω4+1);b3=σ{α(1+β)κHω2}/(ω4+1);b4=(ασ)/(ω4+1);b2={ασ(1+β)+κFς}/(ω4+1);b3=σ{α(1+β)κFω2}/(ω4+1).

Note that trade openness influences the coefficients of the IS relations and the Phillips curves. One of the key parameters is an index of openness, α, which corresponds to the share of domestic consumption allocated to imported goods. For example, a high degree of trade openness (α ↑) can make the demand and supply schedule shift to the right (or the left) (a1,a2,b1,b2,b3,b4,b2,b3).

z~t is used to denote the state vector of [xtπtrtxtπtrt]. The structural model of a symmetric open economy can be rewritten in canonical form:

(14)A~E~tz~t+1+B~z~t+C~z~t1=0,

where:

A~=[1a10a200b1β0b100000000a2001a10b100b1β0000000],B~=[10a1a200b210b300(1c1)c3(1c1)c21000a20010ab300b210000(1c1)c3(1c1)c21],C~=[000000b400b40000c1000000000b400b40000000c1].

The method of undetermined coefficients and iterative methods can be used to solve the system of equations. This solution indicates the equilibrium values of the observable variables in the system.

References

Adolfson, M., S. Lasen, J. Lind, and M. Villani. 2005. “The Role of Sticky Prices in an Open Economy DSGE Model: A Bayesian Investigation.” Journal of the European Economic Association 3: 444–457.10.1162/jeea.2005.3.2-3.444Search in Google Scholar

Akerlof, G. A. 2002. “Behavioral Macroeconomics and Macroeconomic Behavior.” American Economic Review 92: 411–433.10.1257/00028280260136192Search in Google Scholar

Amato, J. D., and T. Laubach. 2003. “Rule-of-Thumb Behaviour and Monetary Policy.” European Economic Review 47 (5): 791–831.10.1016/S0014-2921(02)00270-2Search in Google Scholar

Anderson, R. B. 2001. “The Power Law as an Emergent Property.” Memory & Cognition 29: 1061–1068.10.3758/BF03195767Search in Google Scholar

Benati, L. 2008. “Investigating Inflation Persistence Across Monetary Regimes.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 123 (3): 1005–1060.10.1162/qjec.2008.123.3.1005Search in Google Scholar

Benigno, P. 2009. “Price Stability with Imperfect Financial Integration.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 41: 121–149.10.1111/j.1538-4616.2008.00201.xSearch in Google Scholar

Berge, T. J. 2012. “Has Globalization Increased the Synchronicity of International Business Cycles?” Economic Review Third Quarter 2012: 5–39.Search in Google Scholar

Bernanke, B. S., M. Gertler, and S. Gilchrist. 1999. “The Financial Accelerator in a Quantitative Business Cycle Framework.” Handbook of Macroeconomics 1: 1341–1393.10.1016/S1574-0048(99)10034-XSearch in Google Scholar

Binder, M., and M. H. Pesaran. 1995. “Multivariate Rational Expectations Models and Macroeconomic Modelling: A Review and Some New Results.” In Handbook of Applied Econometrics: Macroeconomics, edited by M. H. Pesaran and M. Wickens, 139–187. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Search in Google Scholar

Biondi, Y., and S. Righi. 2013. “What does the Financial Market Pricing Do? A Simulation Analysis with a View to Systemic Volatility, Exuberance and Vagary.” Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination 11: 1–29.10.2139/ssrn.2355719Search in Google Scholar

Branch, W. A., and B. McGough. 2009. “A New Keynesian Model with Heterogeneous Expectations.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 33 (5): 1036–1051.10.1016/j.jedc.2008.11.007Search in Google Scholar

Brock, W. A., and C. H. Hommes. 1997. “A Rational Route to Randomness.” Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 65: 1059–1095.10.2307/2171879Search in Google Scholar

Bryant, J. 1987. “The Paradox of Thrift, Liquidity Preference and Animal Spirits.” Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 55: 1231–1235.10.2307/1911271Search in Google Scholar

Da Silveira, M. 2006. “Two-Country New Keynesian DSGE Model: A Small Open Economy as a Limit Case.” IPEA Discussion Paper No. 1157.Search in Google Scholar

De Grauwe, P. 2011. “Animal Spirits and Monetary Policy.” Economic Theory 47 (2–3): 423–457.10.1007/s00199-010-0543-0Search in Google Scholar

De Grauwe, P. 2012. Lectures on Behavioral Macroeconomics. Princeton University Press.10.2307/j.ctvcmxp1gSearch in Google Scholar

Driscoll, J. C., and S. Holden. 2014. “Behavioral Economics and Macroeconomic Models.” Journal of Macroeconomics 41: 133–147.10.1016/j.jmacro.2014.05.004Search in Google Scholar

Engel, C., and A. Matsumoto. 2006. Portfolio Choice in a Monetary Open-Economy DSGE Model. National Bureau of Economic Research, No. w12214.10.3386/w12214Search in Google Scholar

Faia, E., and T. Monacelli. 2008. “Optimal Monetary Policy in a Small Open Economy with Home Bias.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 40 (4): 721–750.10.1111/j.1538-4616.2008.00133.xSearch in Google Scholar

Fuhrer, J. C. 2000. “Habit Formation in Consumption and its Implications for Monetary Policy Models.” American Economic Review 90 (3): 367–390.10.1257/aer.90.3.367Search in Google Scholar

Fuhrer, J. C. 2010. “Inflation Persistence.” In Handbook of Monetary Economics, edited by B. M. Friedman and M. Woodford, Vol. 3A. Elsevier.10.1016/B978-0-444-53238-1.00009-0Search in Google Scholar

Galí, J., and M. Gertler. 1999. “Inflation Dynamics: A Structural Econometric Analysis.” Journal of Monetary Economics 44: 195–222.10.1016/S0304-3932(99)00023-9Search in Google Scholar

Galí, J., and T. Monacelli. 2005. “Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Volatility in a Small Open Economy.” Review of Economic Studies 72: 707–734.10.1111/j.1467-937X.2005.00349.xSearch in Google Scholar

Grilli, R., G. Tedeschi, and M. Gallegati. 2014. “Bank Interlinkages and Macroeconomic Stability.” International Review of Economics & Finance 34: 72–88.10.1016/j.iref.2014.07.002Search in Google Scholar

Jang, T.-S., and E. Okano. 2015. “Productivity Shocks and Monetary Policy in a Two-Country Model.” Frontiers of Economics in China 10 (1): 7–37.Search in Google Scholar

Jang, T.-S., and S. Sacht. 2016. “Animal Spirits and the Business Cycle: Empirical Evidence from Moment Matching.” Metroeconomica 67 (1): 76–113.10.1111/meca.12091Search in Google Scholar

Jang, T.-S., and S. Sacht. 2019. “Forecast Heuristics, Consumer Expectations, and New-Keynesian Macroeconomics: A Horse Race.” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization forthcoming. doi: 10.1016/j.jebo.2019.01.017.10.1016/j.jebo.2019.01.017Search in Google Scholar

Kollmann, R. 2013. “Global Banks, Financial Shocks, and International Business Cycles: Evidence from an Estimated Model.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 45 (s2): 159–195.10.1111/jmcb.12074Search in Google Scholar

Kose, M. A., E. S. Prasad, and M. E. Terrones. 2003. How does Globalization Affect the Synchronization of Business Cycles? IZA Discussion Paper, No. 702.10.2139/ssrn.879102Search in Google Scholar

Lengnick, M., and H. W. Wohltmann. 2013. “Agent-Based Financial Markets and New Keynesian Macroeconomics: A Synthesis.” Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination 8 (1): 1–32.10.1007/s11403-012-0100-ySearch in Google Scholar

Lengnick, M., and H. W. Wohltmann. 2014. “Optimal Monetary Policy in a New Keynesian Model with Animal Spirits and Financial Markets.” Economics Working Paper, Christian-Albrechts-Universität Kiel, No. 2014-12.Search in Google Scholar

Matheson, T. 2010. “Assessing the Fit of Small Open Economy DSGEs.” Journal of Macroeconomics 32 (3): 906–920.10.1016/j.jmacro.2009.10.001Search in Google Scholar

Middleton, E. 1996. “Adaptation Level and ‘animal spirits’.” Journal of Economic Psychology 17 (4): 479–498.10.1016/0167-4870(96)00020-7Search in Google Scholar

Obstfeld, M., and K. Rogoff. 1995. “Exchange Rate Dynamics Redux.” Journal of Political Economy 103: 624–660.10.1086/261997Search in Google Scholar

Pech, W., and M. Milan. 2009. “Behavioral Economics and the Economics of Keynes.” Journal of Socio-Economics 38 (6): 891–902.10.1016/j.socec.2009.06.011Search in Google Scholar

Proano, C. R. 2011. “Exchange Rate Determination, Macroeconomic Dynamics and Stability Under Heterogeneous Behavior FX Expectations. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 77: 177–188.10.1016/j.jebo.2010.10.005Search in Google Scholar

Ravenna, F., and C. Walsh. 2006. “Optimal Monetary Policy with the Cost Channel.” Journal of Monetary Economics 53 (2): 199–216.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2005.01.004Search in Google Scholar

Rudebusch, G. D., B. P. Sack, and E. T. Swanson. 2006. “Macroeconomic Implications of Changes in the Term Premium.” FRB of San Francisco Working Paper, pp. 2006–2046.10.2139/ssrn.1006838Search in Google Scholar

Sheedy, K. D. 2010. “Intrinsic Inflation Persistence.” Journal of Monetary Economics 57 (8): 1049–1061.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2010.10.002Search in Google Scholar

Smets, Frank, and Raf Wouters. 2003 (9) 1. “An Estimated Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model of the Euro Area.” Journal of the European Economic Association 1 (5): 1123–1175.10.1162/154247603770383415Search in Google Scholar

Smets, Frank, and Rafael Wouters. 2007 (5). “Shocks and Frictions in US Business Cycles: A Bayesian DSGE Approach.” American Economic Review 97 (3): 586–606.10.1257/aer.97.3.586Search in Google Scholar

Tille, C. 2008. “Financial Integration and the Wealth Effect of Exchange Rate Fluctuations.” Journal of International Economics 75 (2): 283–294.10.1016/j.jinteco.2008.02.003Search in Google Scholar

Tovar, C. E. 2009. “DSGE Models and Central Banks.” Open-Assessment E-Journal 3: 2009–2016.10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2009-16Search in Google Scholar

Vriend, N. J. 1996. “Rational Behavior and Economic Theory.” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 29 (2): 263–285.10.1016/0167-2681(95)00063-1Search in Google Scholar

Wang, P., and Y. Wen. 2007. “Inflation Dynamics: A Cross-Country Investigation.” Journal of Monetary Economics 54 (7): 2004–2031.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2006.07.007Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2019-12-12

©2020 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 4.5.2024 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejm-2016-0141/html
Scroll to top button