The joint production of confidence – self-regulation in European crowdfunding markets

Ana Odorović (Faculty of Law, Institute for Law and Economics, University of Hamburg, Hamburg, Germany)
Karsten Wenzlaff (Faculty of Business, Economics, and Social Sciences and Chair Digital Markets, University of Hamburg, Hamburg, Germany)

Baltic Journal of Management

ISSN: 1746-5265

Article publication date: 25 March 2020

Issue publication date: 2 June 2020

2536

Abstract

Purpose

The paper discusses the rationale for a widespread reliance on Codes of Conduct (CoC) in European crowdfunding through the lenses of economic theories of self-regulation. By analysing the institutional design of CoCs in crowdfunding, the paper illustrates the differences in their regulatory context, inclusiveness, monitoring and enforcement. It offers the first systematic overview of substantial rules of CoCs in crowdfunding.

Design/methodology/approach

A comparative case study of nine CoCs in Europe is used to illustrate differences in their institutional design and discern the economic purpose of the CoC.

Findings

The institutional design of different CoCs in Europe mainly supports voluntary theories of self-regulation. In particular, the theory of reputation commons has the most explanatory power. The substantial rules of CoC in different markets show the potential sources of market failure through the perspectives of platforms.

Research limitations/implications

CoCs appear in various regulatory, cultural, and industry contexts of different countries. Some of the institutional design features of CoC might be a result of these characteristics.

Practical implications

Crowdfunding associations wishing to develop their own CoC may learn from a comparative overview of key provisions.

Social implications

For governments in Europe, contemplating creating or revising bespoke crowdfunding regimes, the paper identifies areas where crowdfunding platforms perceive market failure.

Originality/value

This paper is the first systematic study of self-regulatory institutions in European crowdfunding. The paper employs a theoretical framework for the analysis of self-regulation in crowdfunding and provides a comparison of a regulatory context, inclusiveness, monitoring and enforcement of different CoCs in Europe.

Keywords

Citation

Odorović, A. and Wenzlaff, K. (2020), "The joint production of confidence – self-regulation in European crowdfunding markets", Baltic Journal of Management, Vol. 15 No. 2, pp. 303-331. https://doi.org/10.1108/BJM-04-2019-0119

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2019, Ana Odorović and Karsten Wenzlaff

License

Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) license. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this license may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


1. Introduction

“The promise and perils of crowdfunding” (Armour and Enriques, 2018) are still not entirely known to all stakeholders, policymakers and regulators, who struggle to strike an optimal balance between investor protection and the growth of the sector. Regulatory issues that remain unaddressed as a result lead to uncertainty in the market, which can stifle the growth of an emerging industry. To prevent this, crowdfunding associations across Europe have created Codes of Conduct (CoC). These CoCs complement existing rules by bringing more clarity as to how regulation should be implemented and by introducing new standards of behaviour for crowdfunding platforms.

The practice of drafting and implementing CoC is commonly denoted in the literature of law and economics as private ordering (Schwarcz, 2002). The voluntary association of firms to control their collective behaviour is also known in the social science literature as industry self-regulation (Bowen, 2019; Williams, 2004; Gunningham and Rees, 1997). Literature on private ordering and self-regulation has mainly focused on private ordering of professions, such as lawyers and accountants (Dingwall and Fenn, 1987; Philipsen, 2012; Van den Bergh, 2004), voluntary environmental codes (Howard et al., 2000; Prakash and Potoski, 2007), voluntary corporate governance standards (Belcher, 1996), international accountability standards (Gilbert et al., 2011), self-regulation in banking (Stefanadis, 2003) and the ethics of industry self-regulation (Bowen, 2019).

This paper aims to answer the question of what motivates crowdfunding platforms to enact the rules of CoC. Drawing on the economic theory of self-regulation and the theory of clubs, this paper outlines a theoretical framework for the study of CoCs in crowdfunding, focusing on the context of their emergence and various institutional dimensions. Since this paper focusses on the institutional design of CoCs, it will not analyse the actual implementation of the CoCs by the platforms.

Existing literature on self-regulation in the crowdfunding sector is very scarce. Schwienbacher (2014) briefly explains the merits of a CoC in crowdfunding. He argues that a CoC sets the basis for the behaviour of the platforms and provides recommendations for the interaction between platforms, investors and projects. Jegelevičiūtė and Valančienė (2015) make a brief reference of the CoCs of the UK Crowdfunding Association, the Financement Participatif France and the European Crowdfunding Network as one of the means to promote the crowdfunding industry. Turan (2015) briefly refers to the CoC discussions in the European Crowdfunding Stakeholder Forum in 2014, where the ECN Code of Conduct and the Peer-to-Peer Finance Associations Principles were discussed, as part of discussions on the regulatory framework in Europe. Wenzlaff (2019) discusses the maturity of crowdfunding ecosystems and contends that CoCs emerge only in later stages of crowdfunding market development. Kshetri (2015, p. 11) argues that crowdfunding is more likely to be successful “in an economy characterized by the existence of crowdfunding-related trade associations”. Such associations also serve to coordinate behaviour of its members and overcome the gaps in existing regulatory frameworks. Similarly, Lehner and Harrer (2019, p. 76) emphasise the role of platforms in contributing to overall standards, norms and traditions in crowdfunding.

This paper contributes to the study of market-based solutions to information asymmetries in financial markets and the broader crowdfunding literature by providing the first glimpse into the crowdfunding self-regulation. The contribution is twofold. Firstly, drawing on existing theories of self-regulation, the paper elaborates a theoretical framework which links the institutional design of CoCs to their economic purpose. Secondly, a comparative case study highlights common features as well as diversity in the institutional design among CoC in different European countries and relates them to specific solutions to collective action problems that affect the efficiency of codes. Although the topic of the paper is closely related to studies of business and management science, the approach taken is closely aligned with research in the field of law and economics.

This paper is structured in the following way. The second section discusses existing theories of self-regulation and characteristics of the crowdfunding market which prompt self-regulation. It also proposes a theoretical framework for the study of the institutional design of CoCs of crowdfunding associations. The third section explains the methodology to identify the case studies of different CoCs in Europe and to cluster substantial provisions contained in CoCs. The fourth section analyses the CoCs in the light of the theory of self-regulation and discusses variation in institutional features of CoCs across Europe. The fifth section concludes and provides directions for further research.

2. Theoretical framework for self-regulation in crowdfunding

2.1 Literature review of the theory of self-regulation

In the legal scholarship and the scholarship of law and economics, self-regulation is understood as collective rules of conduct which do not originate from the government. These rules are meant to produce market outcomes which would not have been achieved if market participants were left to market forces alone (Ogus, 1995, p. 587). Self-regulation is taken to imply “the situation of a group of persons or bodies, acting together, performing a regulatory function in respect of themselves and others who accept their authority” (Black, 1996, p. 27). It helps achieving “public policy objectives at lower cost than government regulation” because of the information advantage which industry representatives have over regulators (Bowen, 2019, p. 257). As opposed to formal institutions of the state, self-regulation belongs to informal, private and social institutions, which may also serve to facilitate search and information by members of society (Dixit, 2009). Self-regulating institutions can imply one or several functions: formulation of rules, their interpretation, resolving disputes among group members and enforcement, which usually includes some form of sanctions (Black, 1996).

However, self-regulation does not necessarily imply an absence of government. Four ways in which state actors can relate to self-regulatory groups and bodies are (Black, 1996, p. 27):

  1. Mandated self-regulation: the government delegates regulatory powers to self-regulatory groups;

  2. Sanctioned regulation: the government approves rules drafted by the self-regulatory group;

  3. Coerced self-regulation: as a response to a rising threat of government regulation not tailed to industry's needs, self-regulatory groups create standards;

  4. Voluntary self-regulation: without government engagement of any kind, members of an industry or a profession create common standards for the behaviour of market participants.

Rules formulated by self-regulatory groups can be legally binding or non-binding (Ogus, 1995, p. 589). The breach of legally binding rules leads to private or public law consequences. The breach of non-binding rules leads to deprivation of certain rights within a group or association, such as ostracism. Sometimes non-binding regimes allow group members to opt out from certain norms, as long as a more appropriate behaviour can be demonstrated. Self-regulatory rules formulated as recommendations on a voluntary basis lead to no sanctions in case of non-compliance.

The question of the advantages and disadvantages of self-regulation is central in discussing the effectiveness of such a framework. Van den Bergh (2004, p. 3–8) argues that self-regulation is desired in industries in which market participants possess information advantage over regulators. This information advantage allows the creation of more suitable rules and achieves cost savings in relation to the enforcement of the rules. On the other hand, industry members lack democratic legitimacy to create and enforce rules. A lack of governmental oversight might lead to an abuse of self-regulatory powers to restrict competition.

The emergence of self-regulatory organisations depends on its advantages for the companies bound by the self-regulatory framework. Self-regulation, similarly to government regulation, is a result of a market failure in the form of information asymmetries, externalities or public goods. On the assumption of unconstrained competition among firms, which internalise all the costs of their activities, and well-informed consumers, who can choose the supplier with the best quality, regulatory rules would not be necessary. Under this assumption, firms that opt for low-quality standards would be forced to leave the market.

Self-regulation, as was described in relation to the emergence of law in primitive societies (Benson, 1988; Posner, 1980), is based on voluntary reciprocal arrangements. Members of an industry or a profession are willing to comply with self-regulatory norms if they can expect that other members will also adhere to such norms. The adherence to and sustainability of self-regulatory regimes depend on the ability of the group to enforce rules. The most common mechanisms of enforcement are the threat of expulsion of the non-compliant member and temporary suspension of membership rights.

Theories explaining the emergence of private ordering emphasise either the “coerced” or the “voluntary” nature of self-regulatory institutions, both are discussed in detail further.

One strand of economic literature emphasises that self-regulatory rules and organisations emerge because of a threat of government regulation. Maxwell et al. (2000) argue that firms are willing to reduce their harmful behaviour in order to save on political transaction costs associated with government regulations. These costs stem from organising themselves to influence policymakers once they enter into a political process (p. 586). Stefanadis (2003) develops a model that explains the emergence of self-regulation in an innovative industry in which new products are developed. Self-regulatory organisations can be regarded as a “club owned by industry participants” (Stefanadis, 2003, p. 5). Their incentive to introduce self-regulatory standards is to prevent the bureaucratic delays associated with ex-ante approval of new products in the system of statutory regulations. The advantage of an industry club formulating and enforcing regulatory rules is its superior knowledge about new technologies, which allows the club members to save on costs of delaying new products.

The other strand of economic literature assumes that self-regulation emerges independently of the government intervention on a voluntary basis to expand or complement existing regulation. Due to information asymmetries, consumers are unable to distinguish between the product qualities of different firms whose products typically represent credence or experience goods[1]. It might be profitable for a firm to offer higher standards, yet it might as well be prohibitively costly to produce credible signals of quality. Under conditions of uncertainty, adverse selection emerges (Akerlof, 1978). Gehrig and Jost (1995) explain that self-regulation of industry members serves as a signal of quality to outsiders. Industry members have strong incentives to enforce and punish any member that deviates, given that a failure to comply with industry standards weakens the signal of the entire club.

Prakash and Potoski (2007) explain why companies adhere to voluntary rules whose purpose is to reduce negative externalities. Industry members who pursue voluntary programmes create a club, as an “institution that supplies impure public goods” (Prakash and Potoski, 2007, p. 776). Impure public or club goods are used within the meaning of the Buchanan theory (Buchanan, 1965) as goods that are exclusively used by the members of a club in a non-rivalrous way. In this context, club goods are “affiliation with the club positive brand reputation” (Prakash and Potoski, 2007, p. 777) and are only available to those industry members who incur the costs of producing positive (reducing negative) externalities. Both Gehrig and Jost (1995) and Prakash and Potoski (2007) emphasise that self-regulation overcomes the free-rider problem of public goods by introducing mechanisms of exclusion of those club members who do not incur the costs of protecting club's reputation.

Gorton and Mullineaux (1987) and Yue and Ingram (2012) argue that the reputations of different firms in the same industry are interrelated. A non-compliance by one member breaking the trust of consumers harms the reputation of the industry. Adherence to high-quality standards by competitors creates a positive image of the industry, splitting rewards among all members. Yue and Ingram (2012) claim that “reputation commons” cause the emergence of self-regulation in industries where “outsiders are not equipped with specialised knowledge to distinguish between the behaviours of the industry's individual members” (Yue and Ingram, 2012, p. 6). It is in the self-interest of market participants to cooperate with respect to setting and enforcing rules. Cooperation among industry members allows for mutual benefits that could not be attained through market forces.

The aforementioned theories were developed outside the crowdfunding context in relation to different financial and non-financial industries. They are nevertheless relevant to the crowdfunding market in Europe, given that this industry has been governed by a self-regulatory regime since a few years after its emergence. Platforms in various countries have adopted CoCs, which were drafted and promoted by crowdfunding associations. Self-regulatory regime emerged in very different regulatory contexts, sometimes in anticipation of crowdfunding-specific regulation and in other instances after, or, as a reaction to it. A widespread practice of adopting CoCs in crowdfunding markets in different European jurisdictions raises the question as to which of the aforementioned theories is best able to explain their purpose. Answer to this question has multiple implications for the regulators in these countries, given that the motivation behind this phenomenon is likely to affect the outcomes in these markets. Moreover, the content of self-regulatory rules is informative about which aspects of crowdfunding business are a potential source of market failure.

The following subsection discusses characteristics of crowdfunding markets which provide support for competing theories of self-regulation. The following subsection outlines a theoretical framework for understanding the purpose of CoC in the crowdfunding markets and discusses the motivation to focus on the institutional design of the CoCs.

2.2 Characteristics of the crowdfunding market and the theory of self-regulation

In an attempt to discern the motivation behind a widespread practice of adopting CoCs in different European jurisdictions, it is informative to look at some of the characteristics of the crowdfunding industry.

Several features provide support for the theory of “coerced self-regulation”. Crowdfunding platforms, which act as financial intermediaries between projects and investors, are part of the digital transformation of businesses and profit from the widespread use of social media (Cumming and Hornuf, 2018, p. 12). The novelty of this industry consists of providing new channels of communication and new ways to gather information, which allow investors to assess the viability of projects better. Technological tools to estimate the risk of projects and match it with investors' risk preference are commonly used. From the point of view of projects, the participation of a significant number of investors also generates information about their individual preferences for goods or services they offer. This is commonly denoted as “wisdom of crowds” (Surowiecki, 2005). Crowdfunding platforms have been experimenting with different business models and products, including different financial instruments, tools to pre-select projects and govern investments after the completion of a campaign. Regulatory delay in approving new business models and products may stifle these innovative efforts. This incentivises industry members to develop self-regulatory rules in the form of CoCs, which are more flexible and easily revised, allowing to keep pace with industry developments. In line with Stefanadis (2003, p. 5), self-regulation in crowdfunding, which pre-empts government regulations, can be attributed to continuous technological change in this industry and the requirement to ask for ex-ante permission from the regulator to introduce new products and services[2]. Similarly, (Lehner and Harrer, 2019, p. 89) argue that crowdfunding platforms have an incentive to work together to inform and influence legislation to enhance the current regulatory status. These arguments are consistent with empirical findings that the “changes to regulations” are ranked as one of the highest risk factors by platforms operating different business models (Ziegler et al., 2019, p. 53–54).

Support for theories of “voluntary self-regulation” comes from the nature of services that crowdfunding platforms offer, which can be characterised as “credence goods” (Darby and Karni, 1973, p. 69; Nelson, 1970). Investors are often not able to judge the quality of platforms' service neither before nor right after their experience on the platform. Crowdfunding platforms have a specific “look and feel” which make them indistinguishable from other platforms at first sight. The presentation of projects on a platform often includes a pitch video, a project description, a team section and a bar graph displaying the volume funded by the crowd[3]. The similarity of the websites' designs across the industry stems from the interaction between competitors duplicating successful website layouts. By providing user interfaces which are known to potential investors, thus, reducing the switching costs between platforms, market players increase the likelihood of investment. The layout can be replicated at low cost by a new entrant. Thus, the setting up of the platform does not serve as a credible signal of quality. The recognisable design increases the costs for an investor to infer the quality of platforms' services which are relevant for the selection of a platform such as fees, due diligence of projects, operational infrastructure, data protection standards and post-campaign services. The “credence” nature of these services is reinforced by the fact that retail investors typically pledge small amounts of money which do not justify high costs of platforms' comparison. As a result, platforms which offer high-quality service are unable to distinguish themselves from low-quality ones. In addition, they are likely to experience negative reputational spillovers from platforms which deceived investors (Akerlof, 1978).

In line with the voluntary self-regulation theory of Gehrig and Jost (1995) and Prakash and Potoski (2007), crowdfunding platforms have an incentive to coordinate their behaviour. They create club-like institutions which enforce rules for high-quality service. Such institutions are embedded in CoCs, which stipulate substantial rules of platforms' behaviour, as well as procedural rules of enforcement. Through the mechanism of a threat of exclusion of those platforms unwilling to adhere to the high standards, platforms ensure that high standards of service are achieved and benefits enjoyed by complying members. Enforcement can also be achieved through the withdrawal of specific rights, such as the right to make public their membership in the club-like institution. These rules also serve as a means to restrict competition by increasing barriers to market entry.

The emergence of CoCs in the early stages of industry development underpins an argument that it is a means to protect “reputation commons”. When CoCs were introduced in different European countries, the crowdfunding industry was going through a legitimisation process, which has a cognitive and socio-political component (Aldrich and Fiol, 1994, p. 648). Cognitive legitimisation refers to the public knowledge about crowdfunding activity, whereas socio-political legitimisation implies public acceptance of the industry as appropriate and economically viable. As shown by Jegelevičiūtė and Valančienė (2015), CoCs are one of the tools through which the crowdfunding industry is promoted by its members. The interdependence between the individual reputation of platforms and the reputation of the crowdfunding industry has been highlighted in several surveys. Platform operators rank the risk of a failure of a prominent competitor as very high (Ziegler et al., 2018) suggesting that “reputation commons” are threatened. However, the existence of separate CoCs for lending- and equity-based crowdfunding, such as in the United Kingdom, suggests that the fear of a failure does not necessarily transcend the business models of crowdfunding. Equity-based crowdfunding platforms might not be afraid of a failure of a lending platform, and vice versa.

Different characteristics of the crowdfunding market are able to underpin both “coerced” and “voluntary” theories of self-regulation and explain the widespread reliance on CoCs. Unlike in traditional financial markets, many aspects of the crowdfunding activity are left to platforms to choose, even in jurisdictions which have adopted bespoke crowdfunding regime – which are regulatory regimes that are tailored to the technological specifics of crowdfunding markets. This leeway of platforms is a result of incompleteness of existing regulations, uncertainty regarding inherent risks, or platforms' innovative efforts which can result in circumvention of applicable rules. In many instances, the applicability of certain laws that are not crowdfunding-specific is subject to ambiguous interpretations.

In the following subsection, this paper will discuss how the institutional design of CoCs can explain the emergence of self-regulation in crowdfunding markets.

2.3 Institutional design of codes of conduct and the theory of self-regulation

Mere features of the crowdfunding industry do not provide a definite answer which of the theoretical explanation is the most plausible. In contrast, the institutional design of the chosen self-regulatory regime provides better guidance. In the rest of this section, the paper argues that if the CoC is rationally designed, some of the institutional features can reveal the rationale for the adoption of CoCs. In relation to this, the paper outlines a simple theoretical framework for the study of CoCs in the crowdfunding industry, which builds upon competing theories of self-regulation discussed earlier.

Each of the three theories of self-regulation (“coerced theory”, “club theory”, and “reputation common theory”) emphasise a different economic problem that market players are trying to solve when adopting and adhering to self-regulatory rules. As a consequence, the institutional design of CoCs is expected to reflect the underlying rationale for their adoption.

The “coerced theory” of self-regulation emphasises the threat of government regulation. As discussed earlier, it is either savings on “political costs” or “costs of delaying the introduction of new products” that motivate market participants to introduce a self-regulatory regime. In order for the industry to be successful at pre-empting or deferring government regulation, the adopted self-regulatory framework must emulate the framework which a government would create. Deferring state regulation implies that CoCs are introduced before crowdfunding-specific regime, although it is conceivable that “coerced CoCs” appear with the intention of deferring further revisions of the crowdfunding-specific regime. Given that government regulations would be mandatory for all members of the industry, “coerced CoCs” are likely to be open for signing by all platforms (of a particular business model pertaining to the perceived scope of the regulation). Given that government regulation relies on centralised monitoring by the regulator and robust enforcement mechanisms, “coerced CoCs” are expected to have a similar institutional design. For instance, in a “coerced CoC”, a crowdfunding association is likely to take over the monitoring and enforcement role. As to the content of substantial rules of CoCs, a “coerced CoC” would create new obligations for platforms. Such a CoC would not emphasise rules already written in laws and regulations, as these are already enforced by the regulator.

P1.

Platforms creating CoCs to stifle government regulation, in accordance with “coerced theory”, are more likely to opt for rules which:

  1. precede the introduction of crowdfunding-specific regulatory regime;

  2. target all market participants (inclusive membership);

  3. create strong and centralised monitoring by the crowdfunding association;

  4. introduce strong enforcement mechanisms;

  5. do not restate obligations which are already required by existing laws and regulations.

Voluntary theories of self-regulation deny that self-regulation is primarily a result of a threat of government regulation. Instead, voluntary theories of self-regulation propose that it is in the best interest of market participants to create rules which would help them resolve the collective action problem inherent in public goods or the issue of overuse of commons. “Club goods” theories assume that self-regulations resolve the problem of free riding in relation to industry reputation by creating a club of close-knit market participants. These market participants comply with self-regulatory rules in order to benefit from a credible signal of quality. For the signal to be credible, the institutional design of the self-regulatory regime has to solve the issue of excludability of non-compliant industry members.

In the crowdfunding context, “club good” rationale for CoCs entails that a membership will be limited to few platforms willing to adhere to high-quality standards, which will be clearly distinguishable from the rest of the industry. A right to display a logo or other label associated with a CoC is likely to be prominently displayed. Unlike “coerced CoCs” which are likely to appear before state regulations, CoCs that create a club of quality platforms are likely to appear both before and after state regulations. A self-regulatory club can emerge in a regulated environment as well because incomplete, unclear or insufficient laws and regulations are a threat to market participants aiming to provide high-quality services. In order for exclusion to be a credible threat, such CoCs are likely to introduce strong monitoring and enforcement mechanisms. However, unlike “coerced CoCs”, decentralised monitoring, in which platforms supervise compliance of each other, is likely to be also introduced. This is due to the fact that small membership base leads to reduced costs of monitoring as well as transaction costs of coordinating monitoring efforts. Since excludability lies in the definition of a club, CoCs that serve as a club-like institution are expected to have strong enforcement mechanisms in place which would ensure compliance. Given that self-regulatory clubs serve as a quality signal, this signal might as well be used to demonstrate compliance with existing state regulations. As such, substantial rules of CoC are likely to restate platforms' obligations, which are already required by existing laws and regulations.

P2.

Platforms creating CoCs with the purpose of excluding non-complying members, in accordance with “club good theories”, are more likely to opt for rules which:

  1. precede the introduction of the crowdfunding-specific regulatory regime or follow and complement an existing one;

  2. target a limited number of market participants (exclusive membership);

  3. create strong centralised and/or decentralised monitoring;

  4. introduce strong enforcement mechanisms;

  5. create new rules and/or restate obligations which are already required by existing laws and regulations.

“Reputation commons” theory considers self-regulation as a means to overcome the issue of overuse of commons. In the crowdfunding market, industry reputation is being “overused” because platforms cannot internalise all the costs they create for the industry reputation when lowering the quality of their service. Low-quality service of platforms creates spillover effects for the entire industry, given the interconnectedness of the reputation of all industry members. As a consequence, CoCs are likely to create rules which will help to get all market participants “on board”, by increasing the benefits of cooperation or increasing the costs of deviation. Similarly to other voluntary theories of self-regulation, the adoption of CoCs is independent of the time of introducing state regulations in a particular jurisdiction. Inclusive membership of such CoCs also dictates monitoring and enforcement mechanisms. Due to a large number of members, monitoring is likely to be delegated to a crowdfunding association or another designated body. However, their monitoring powers might be weak due to the resistance of smaller platforms to more intrusive methods of detecting non-compliance. As a result of a compromise of a large number of actors, rules are likely to reflect the common ground among them. Consequentially, weak monitoring is often accompanied by weak enforcement. As to the content of CoCs substantial provisions, both new rules and reference to existing rules are likely to be included, since industry reputation is equally at stake when existing laws are not adequately implemented.

P3.

Platforms creating CoCs with the purpose of protecting industry reputation, in accordance with “reputation commons theories”, are more likely to opt for rules which:

  1. precede the introduction of the crowdfunding-specific regulatory regime or follow and complement an existing one;

  2. target all market participants (inclusive membership);

  3. create weak/centralised monitoring;

  4. introduce weak enforcement mechanisms;

  5. create new rules and/or restate obligations which are already required by existing laws and regulations.

Table I summarises the theoretical framework outlined earlier, emphasising common institutional dimensions between existing theories as well as their distinctive dimensions.

In conclusion, the three competing theories share many institutional characteristics. The main argument of distinction between “coerced” and “club goods” theories is exclusive membership, decentralised enforcement and reference to existing laws, which are likely to appear in relation to club-like institutions. Self-regulatory regimes which emerge as a response to a threat of government intervention are also unlikely to have in place weak monitoring and enforcement mechanisms inherent in the institutional design of CoCs that aim to protect reputation commons. Finally, the difference between the two voluntary theories of self-regulation lies in the inclusiveness of membership and efficacy of monitoring and enforcement mechanisms.

The rest of the paper relies on this theoretical framework to discuss what the institutional design of CoCs adopted in different European jurisdictions suggests about the economic rationale for self-regulation in crowdfunding.

3. Methodology of case studies

This paper conducts a comparative case study of the existing CoC in the crowdfunding markets (comparative case study) (Yin, 2014).

In line with crowdfunding literature (Belleflamme et al., 2014; Blohm et al., 2013; Haas et al. , 2014; Hemer et al., 2011), the paper uses the term “crowdfunding” to denote all four business models (donation-based, reward-based, equity-based and lending-based crowdfunding). The use of this term does not necessarily coincide with its narrower use in some CoCs.

The focus of this paper is on CoCs in European Crowdfunding markets, since comparable frameworks regulate platforms headquartered in the European Union. The authors of this paper were able to verify their findings with representatives of crowdfunding associations in Europe, which additionally made the focus on European CoCs reasonable.

The authors focused on CoCs by crowdfunding associations. The existence of association-wide CoCs does not prevent platforms from having their own CoCs. Desk-based research of the most significant crowdfunding platforms found that platforms describe the relationship with their users in specific terms, which are part of the contractual arrangements between platforms and investors. The duties imposed by the CoCs of associations shape the contractual arrangements on a platform. For instance, the German Crowdfunding Association requests projects to report regularly to investors. Members of the German Crowdfunding Association have to implement these reporting standards into their terms. The implementation of the association-wide CoCs into platform terms is beyond the scope of this paper but will be part of future research by the authors.

To assess if and where CoCs exist in the field of crowdfunding, the authors conducted desk-based research. The first step was to create a list of associations of crowdfunding platforms in Europe, download and translate the CoCs found on the websites of the platforms. The authors reached out to representatives of the associations, especially to verify the year of adoption of the CoC and the year of adoption of the respective crowdfunding regulatory framework. In addition, the authors used the common search engines for terms such as “Code of Conduct Crowdfunding” and “Best Practice Guidelines Crowdfunding”. The term “Crowdfunding” was exchanged with more specific terms such as “Crowdinvesting”, “Equity-based Crowdfunding”, “Peer-to-Peer-Lending” or “Lending-based Crowdfunding”.

The Internet search might not have captured all existing CoCs since not always the term “Code of Conduct” is used. For instance, the Austrian CoC is published under the name “Standesregeln” (rules of the branch). Therefore, the authors reached out to crowdfunding experts and representatives of crowdfunding associations to verify the existence and details of CoCs. If the statutes of the association referred to the CoC, the authors included the statutes in the analysis. Still, this paper might not have captured all rules related to the behaviour of members inside associations. For instance, the German Crowdfunding Association has a separate document which organises the mandate of the board (Vorstands-Geschäftsordnung), which is not published by the association. The authors concluded that the analysis of all statutes would have been beyond the scope of this paper.

The sample did not include all found CoCs. The website www.crowdsourcing.org developed the Crowdfunding Accreditation for Platform Standards (CAPS). Crowdsourcing.org also created the first global market reports (Massolution, 2015). The CAPS programme was active between 2010 and 2012 and accredited mostly Anglo-American platforms. The standards developed by Crowdsourcing.org are no longer available for analysis. The impact of the CAPS programme on CoCs in the United Kingdom can therefore not be assessed.

The Spanish Crowdfunding Association released a CoC for investors (Asociación Espanola de Crowdfunding, 2018), which outlines the tax provisions for supporters and investors. Since this CoC does not regulate platform behaviour or project owner behaviour, the authors did not include this CoC in the analysis.

The EU-financed project CrowdFundPort includes three equity-based crowdfunding platforms which were asked to create a CoC for crowdfunding platforms in Germany, Austria, Italy, Hungary, Czech Republic, Slovakia, Poland, Slovenia, Croatia) (CrowdfundPort, 2016). The Austrian and German CoC existed before the publication of the CrowdfundPort recommendations. No crowdfunding association exists in Italy, Hungary, Czech Republic, Slovakia, Poland, Slovenia or Croatia. The authors concluded that no crowdfunding associations implemented the recommendations and did not include this document in the analysis.

In total, the authors found 12 CoCs in the crowdfunding market drafted by associations of platforms or platform consortiums (See Table II). The sample includes nine of these 12 CoCs. Two of the CoCs are transnational in character (European CoC and Nordic CoC), while the remaining seven are country-specific CoCs.

A preliminary analysis from this sampling suggested a predominance of CoCs drafted for equity-based and lending-based crowdfunding platforms. Subsection 4.2 discusses the relationship between the CoCs and the business model of the platform. The business model focus of the CoC is derived firstly from a specific mentioning of equity- and lending-based crowdfunding in the CoC; secondly from the content analysis of the provisions which apply only to financial-return-based models such as equity- and lending-based crowdfunding; or thirdly, from the membership structure of the associations. The predominance of this business model of crowdfunding platforms can be explained by the more prevailing fear of market failure in equity-based and lending-based crowdfunding, as discussed in the previous section (Ziegler et al., 2018, 2019).

The European Union is in the process of adopting its European Crowdfunding Service Providers Regime (European Commission, 2018; European Parliament, 2019). In both transnational and national CoCs provisions of the upcoming regulation are found, such as disclosure of default rates and risk warnings. The impact of the CoC of the European Crowdfunding Network (2015) on the Regulatory framework is beyond the research scope of this paper, but anecdotal evidence points out that deliberations in the associations had a formative impact on both the proposal of the European Commission and the adopted position of the European Parliament.

Based on this possible relationship between CoC provisions and emerging regulatory frameworks, the authors used the method of “Grounded theory” and “Open coding” to cluster the content of the provisions (Corbin and Strauss, 2015) The paper proposes a three-tier structure for the analysis of the CoC provisions.

Table III shows an example of the content analysis. The authors translated a provision: a provision focussing on investors’ losses. This provision only appears in the French CoC. The authors then reformulated the provision by clearly stating the obligation. If it was possible to identify the holder of the obligation, then the reformulated provision was phrased as “The platform ensures…” or “The project ensures that…”, as can be seen in Table VII and Table VIII of subsection 4.4.

All provisions underwent a first-level clustering. This paper proposes a first-level clustering with four themes:

  1. Provisions related to the relationship between association and platform (framework)

  2. Provisions related to transparency of either the platform or the project

  3. Provisions related to investor protection

  4. Provisions related to the business conduct of the platform

These three themes are interrelated. An increase in transparency on both the project and the platform protects investors. Better business conduct of the platform protects investors. The authors clustered the provisions on a second level by analysing the context of the provision (Table IV).

Subsection 4.2 discusses the provisions related to the relationship between the association and the members in detail. The paper proposes to differentiate between provisions detailing the purpose of the CoC, provisions detailing who can adhere to the CoC and provisions detailing the monitoring of the members' adherence to the Coc.

Provisions related to transparency and related to investor protection can be clustered according to their relevance before or after the decision of the investor to invest. Transparency provisions can be clearly distinguished by the fact that they formulate specific obligations towards the project or platform. Investor protection provisions relate to terms in either the contract between platform and investor, or the contract between investor and project or both. Business conduct provisions are obligations of the platform. They cannot be grouped along the lines of pre-investment or post-investment process because they refer to ongoing business procedures of the platforms.

Based on the clustering, the authors decided to focus on the framework provisions because these provisions are best suited to relate them to the theoretical framework discussed in the previous section. The findings are discussed in the next section.

4. A comparative study of codes of conduct in the European crowdfunding market

This section analyses the CoC in crowdfunding markets in Europe and discusses their institutional characteristics in relation to economic theories explaining the purpose of self-regulation discussed earlier. The first part of this section discusses the origin of CoCs across different European crowdfunding markets. The second part considers inclusiveness and membership criteria of different CoCs. The third part examines the efficacy of different CoCs as a regulatory tool, based on their monitoring, enforcement and dispute resolution mechanisms. The last part provides an overview of the content of CoCs, that is, their substantial provisions, indicating the issues of transparency, investor protection and good governance that arise in crowdfunding from the lenses of platforms.

4.1 Origins of codes of conduct

Most crowdfunding markets in Europe emerged before a bespoke national crowdfunding regime. A bespoke crowdfunding regime is a regulatory framework designed specifically for crowdfunding activities, platforms and other market participants (such as issuers/borrowers and investors/lenders). Bespoke regimes can differ with respect to the scope and extensiveness of tailored rules.

Existing rules tailored to traditional financial intermediaries are not necessarily applicable and suitable to a nascent industry such as the crowdfunding industry. Yet crowdfunding markets face the same issues that led to extensive regulations in capital markets and banking: market failures associated with asymmetric information and negative externalities. The magnitude of these issues is unknown to policymakers. In some countries, they deferred the adoption of a crowdfunding-specific regulatory regime until the industry reached a certain stage of maturity (Wenzlaff, 2019). In some other countries, regulators introduced bespoke-crowdfunding regimes to stimulate its development. Some empirical evidence shows that there is a high correlation between adequacy of crowdfunding regulations as perceived by platforms and volumes per capita (Ziegler et al., 2019, pp. 55–56). Even in countries with high volumes per capita, some of the relevant questions often remained unaddressed by regulations or gave rise to ambiguities in interpretation. This has created an incentive for platforms to take pre-emptive actions.

Crowdfunding platforms in different countries, usually under the auspices of national or transnational crowdfunding associations, introduced a self-regulatory regime in the form of CoC. Table V provides an overview of the association, the country of origin, the CoC and its denotation in this paper, the year of adoption and the year of adoption of the respective crowdfunding regulatory framework[4].

The study identified nine relevant CoCs in crowdfunding markets in Europe, as listed in Table V. Two of the CoCs are transnational in character (European CoC and Nordic CoC), while the remaining seven are country-specific. The European CoC explicitly states that it does not constitute a court-enforceable regulation and that it does not overrule provisions of national CoCs. No such provisions can be found in the Nordic CoC.

Some CoCs are explicit about the possibility of foreign-based platforms operating in that country to join the crowdfunding association and adhere to the CoC (for instance, UK Crowdfunding CoC and UK Lending CoC). The United Kingdom is the only country where two CoCs were identified (lending- and equity-based crowdfunding).

CoCs of most of the countries were adopted under the umbrella of crowdfunding associations at the national or transnational level. In two countries, the CoC was published by an organisation whose membership is open to companies other than crowdfunding platforms. In Estonia, the CoC was issued by Finance Estonia, an organisation that gathers members from various Fintech industries. In Austria, the CoC was issued by a subsection of the Austrian Chamber of Commerce (Wirtschaftskammer Österreich) – Financial Intermediary (Fachverband Finanzdienstleister), which established a working group on crowdfunding (Arbeitsgruppe Crowdfunding).

CoCs have appeared in countries with most developed crowdfunding market, in terms of either total volumes (the United Kingdom, France, Germany, Netherlands, Nordic Countries, Austria) or volumes per capita (Estonia) (Ziegler et al., 2019). The relationship between the maturity of a crowdfunding market and the existence of CoCs and crowdfunding associations is twofold. CoCs may facilitate the growth of the industry by creating trust among different stakeholders. One of the purposes of crowdfunding associations is to provide institutional coordination among its members to fill out the gaps in regulatory frameworks, thus helping to improve the crowdfunding ecosystem (Kshetri, 2015, p. 102). However, the costs of operating a crowdfunding association and enforcing rules of CoCs become easily justifiable in a consolidated market. Given the number of different factors that affect the development of crowdfunding industry (Rau, 2017), the question of reverse causality between self-regulation and market development would merit further research beyond the scope of this paper.

The CoCs in different European countries originated between 2013 and 2017. Most crowdfunding markets were still nascent, yet facing strong growth. CoCs were either anticipatory or reactionary with respect to crowdfunding regulations. Out of 11 national markets covered in this study, including Nordic countries, five still do not operate under a crowdfunding-specific regulatory regime (Estonia, Norway, Sweden, Denmark and Iceland), yet they are governed by a CoC. Among the jurisdictions with tailored crowdfunding regulations, the United Kingdom saw the emergence of the two CoCs prior to the adoption of statutory regulations. Similarly, the European CoC was created in anticipation of the European Crowdfunding Regime. In line with its Fintech action plan, the European Commission presented a proposal for a regulation on crowdfunding service providers in March 2018, which is currently under review. UK lending-based crowdfunding market is specific for the fact that a bespoke-crowdfunding regime was also revised after the two revisions of the UK Lending CoC in 2019. Therefore, this market features very dynamic interactions between self-regulatory and statutory regimes.

In France, Germany, Netherlands, Austria and Finland, CoCs were created following the adoption of crowdfunding regulations. In several instances, the CoCs were also revised. As mentioned earlier, the UK Lending CoC was revised twice, in 2015 and 2018. The French CoC was revised in 2016. In Germany, the CoC published in 2016 was complemented by the Reporting Guidelines in 2017. In addition to the Guidelines, in 2019, the German Crowdfunding Association produced a list of criteria for receiving a “transparency certificate” or “label” of the association.

The timing of the emergence of CoCs in relation to crowdfunding bespoke regimes may point at the economic rationale for self-regulation in crowdfunding. However, this relationship is complex. By the very definition of anticipatory self-regulatory regimes, it is meant to prevent the forthcoming government intervention. Given that four out of nine CoCs were introduced or revised after crowdfunding-specific regulations, voluntary theories of self-regulation cannot be ruled out. However, as seen in the UK lending-based crowdfunding market, it is also possible that a CoC precedes revisions of the existing crowdfunding regulation. In other words, reactionary CoCs suggest that voluntary theories are likely to prevail in those countries in which revisions of bespoke regimes are not “on the horizon”. Further analysis of the institutional design of different CoCs is necessary to discuss which of the theories of self-regulation is the most convincing in crowdfunding.

4.2 Inclusiveness of codes of conduct

This section examines features of national and transnational CoCs which determine how inclusive membership in self-regulatory institutions is. Inclusiveness in this paper as the scope of business models covered by CoCs, preconditions for becoming a member and the right to display a logo for those platforms who fulfil certain criteria. Although crowdfunding can refer to different business models of operating a platform, the CoCs covered in the analysis of this paper make an explicit or implicit reference to the type of business model addressed.

The paper identified three types of CoCs in relation to covered business models:

  1. CoCs aimed at all business models (Nordic CoC);

  2. CoCs aimed at and restricted to only one business model (UK Lending CoC, Austrian CoC);

  3. CoCs aimed at all business models, yet provisions mainly appropriate for financial-return business models (European CoC, UK Crowdfunding CoC, Estonian CoC, Dutch CoC, German CoC, French CoC).

The UK Lending CoC is the only example of self-regulation restricted to lending-based platforms. The restrictiveness to lending models can only be inferred indirectly, given that the Art. 4 of the Rules of Association stipulate that “any legal entity that operates a Platform is eligible for Membership of the Association provided that entity does substantive business in the UK and meets the Membership criteria published by the Board and amended from time to time.” The membership criteria lay down credit risk and operational risk management procedures and rules on a sound and responsible business model, many of which are meaningless for non-lending platforms. To the knowledge of the authors, the UK Lending Association is the only association for peer-to-peer lending platforms in Europe. However, some lending platforms have joined industry associations in the banking sector and thus have to adhere to the CoCs of these organisations. For instance, in Germany, the Banking Association expanded their membership criteria to include lending platforms. In the Netherlands, the Corporate Finance Association opened their membership to platforms which sign the CoC. In contrast, the Austrian CoC is limited to “operators of crowdinvesting platforms […] within the meaning of § 2 no. 5 AltFG”, which essentially limits the scope of the CoC to equity-based crowdfunding, since this model is covered by the bespoke-crowdfunding regime in Austria.

All other CoCs are open for signing by any type of crowdfunding platform, independently of the business model. For instance, provisions of the Nordic CoC are very general and aimed at all crowdfunding models. The transnational character of the association makes it primarily a tool to foster awareness and legitimise crowdfunding activity. Since members of the Nordic CoC face different regulatory regimes in their home jurisdictions, a more detailed CoC would not be sensible. In contrast to the Nordic CoC, all remaining CoCs (European CoC, UK Crowdfunding CoC, Estonian CoC, Dutch CoC, German CoC, French CoC) contain provisions which indicate that they primarily target financial-return models, in particular, equity-based crowdfunding platforms. For instance, the Reporting Guidelines and the Transparency Certificate of the German CoC contain provisions which are only relevant for equity-based crowdfunding. Thus, it is not surprising that their signatories are overwhelmingly equity-based platforms.

The fact that provisions of CoCs are often more tailored to financial-return crowdfunding (lending- and equity-based crowdfunding), and address donation and reward-based crowdfunding only in general terms, does not indicate that CoCs are meant to constraint membership, in line with “club goods” theories of self-regulation. In the case of donation-based and reward-based crowdfunding, the risks of market failures are simply less pronounced. As a consequence, both the threat of government regulation and reputation spillovers are more likely in relation to financial-return models.

Similarly, the existence of separate CoCs for lending and equity-based platforms in the United Kingdom might as well indicate that reputation spillovers between lending and equity crowdfunding are limited. This is in line with arguments in the literature that reputation externalities are less intense “the more numerous, distant, and heterogeneous are the members” (Barnett, 2006, p. 1763). Alternatively, the limitation of a CoC to a specific business model, such as in the United Kingdom and Austria, may mirror separate regulatory regimes at the state level. In sum, neither explicit nor implicit restrictions of CoCs to a specific business model are enough to conclude that CoCs are driven by an intention to create a club-like institution. However, such restrictions are indicative of the fact that potential market failures are not universal across different models.

In addition to business models, CoCs differ with respect to which platforms are allowed to join a self-regulatory regime. The paper identified three ways in which CoCs restrict who can become their signatory:

  1. only members of the crowdfunding association;[5]

  2. only platforms licensed by the state supervisory authority;

  3. only platforms who fulfil certain criteria (such as annual volumes invested in the platform).

Seven out of nine CoCs apply exclusively to the members of crowdfunding association (European CoC, UK Lending CoC, French CoC, German CoC, Nordic CoC, Dutch CoC, UK Crowdfunding CoC, UK Lending CoC). In Austria, all crowdfunding platforms are required by the law to join the Chamber of Commerce, making the access to CoCs inseparable from membership in the association. The only true exception is the Estonian CoC (Best Practice Guidelines). It is not necessary to be a member of Finance Estonia in order to receive the label of the Best Practice Guidelines, but to follow the Guidelines and report it to Finance Estonia, who conducts checks on the annual basis and decides whether to renew the label.

In essence, restricting access to CoCs to members of the crowdfunding association is not indicative that platforms were aiming at creating club-like institutions. In the case of a large number of platforms, decentralised monitoring and enforcement are too costly to implement. The implementation of CoCs critically depends on the operation of a crowdfunding association which receives monitoring and enforcement powers from the members. Linking adherence to CoCs to adherence to crowdfunding associations is simply a way to cover the costs of implementing a self-regulatory regime.

In two cases, only platforms with a state licence are allowed to join a CoC. The Austrian CoC restricts the access to platforms that are licensed under the bespoke-crowdfunding regime in Austria (Alternativfinanzierungsgesetz). The rules for joining the Nordic Crowdfunding Association require prospective members to provide a statement of authorisation in their home market. In contrast, the UK Crowdfunding CoC specifically states that its rules apply to platforms regardless of whether they are authorised by the state authority.

The Dutch CoC is the only example of restricting membership to platforms which are already operating and fulfil certain requirements. The Dutch CoC stipulates that in order to become a member, platforms need to have at least five projects and must have raised at least 500,000 euros. While not part of CoCs, some statues of crowdfunding associations foresee similar membership criteria. For instance, the statute of the German association requires a platform to have been in operation for at least one year, to have a minimum of five crowdfunding projects and to have raised in total at least 500,000 euros. The rationale for limiting the membership to platforms that fulfil certain criteria is to intensify the quality signal of the club-like institutions. The more constrained the membership, the lower the costs associated with effective enforcement, and thus, the stronger the signal.

Overall, in relation to precondition for platforms to adhere to a self-regulatory regime, restricting membership is an exception rather than a rule. This indicates that, in relation to this criterion, there is more support for the “coerced theory” and “reputation commons theory” than for “club goods theory” of self-regulation.

However, there are three cases in which a specific right is conferred only to platforms who fulfil additional requirements in terms of quality of their service. This right refers to a display of a logo upon verification by the association that additional criteria are met by the platform. As described earlier, the label of the Best Practice Guidelines in Estonian crowdfunding market is only available to those platforms who regularly report to Finance Estonia, which conducts checks on the annual basis and decides whether to renew the label. Similarly, the transparency certificate (logo) of the German crowdfunding association is only available to those members of the association who comply with additional transparency requirements and provide various data to the association once per year, which enable the association to check compliance performance. The German case example is specific for explicitly distinguishing between standard members and those who also adhere to higher transparency standards. Display of a crowdfunding association logo, which is not subject to the fulfilment of any specific criteria verified by the association, is a common practice in various countries. Sometimes this right is explicitly mentioned in the CoC (European CoC, UK Crowdfunding CoC, German CoC, Estonian CoC). Some other associations provide a logo to their members, even though this is not referenced explicitly in the CoC.

The European CoC goes even further in terms of establishing mechanisms that provide credible signals of quality for a limited number of platforms. Art. 2.4 grants rights to ECN to deliver an independent ranking on compliance performance by members of the association. However, these rankings can be published on the ECN website subject to a member's prior acceptance. The ECN has not yet implemented a rating system of compliance. While disclosure of compliance would allow certain industry members to capture “ability rents” (Gorton and Mullineaux, 1987, p. 461), it would also deter a number of platforms from joining the association.

Another interesting provision which creates difference among platforms is known as “comply or explain”. Only two out of nine CoCs (the UK Lending CoC and the Estonian CoC) contain this provision. The “comply-or-explain” procedure can be found in Art. 4 of the Operating Principles of the UK Lending CoC, which also stipulates that waivers have to be approved by the Board Members of the Association and are published on the website of the association. In contrast, the “comply-or-explain” procedure found in the Reporting Form for Compliance in the Estonian CoC forces the platform to publish a deviation from the CoC on its platform. In contrast to the right of a logo, this provision serves to exemplify a non-complying platform, thus, preventing to weaken the quality signal of other members.

In conclusion, it is not a widespread practice to develop specific preconditions for membership as well as conferring certain rights only to a subsample of crowdfunding platforms. Most CoCs opted for a large and unrestricted membership base supporting the argument of either “coerced” or “reputation commons” theory. However, those few exceptional examples described earlier indicate that club-like self-regulatory institutions also emerge in certain crowdfunding markets. The case of German crowdfunding association reconciles both the “club” theory and “reputation commons” theory perspective since it ensures minimum standards for all industry members while at the same time allowing a stronger quality signal from a subsample of platforms. The findings of this section suggest that the rationale for CoCs might not be universal across different markets.

4.3 Monitoring and enforcement of codes of conduct

This section discusses how associations monitor and enforce rules created through CoCs. As to monitoring, which serves to detect platforms who fail to comply with self-regulatory rules, the paper identified three types of obligations borne by platforms:

  1. Information duty – platforms are required to provide the association with information about their compliance;

  2. Denouncing obligation – platforms are required to notify the association about unlawful behaviour of other platforms (including non-compliance with CoC);

  3. Audits – platforms are required to allow audits and reviews by the association.

Table VI provides an overview of monitoring tools in different CoCs. The monitoring mechanisms are put in order according to how strong (efficient) they are, from the weakest (none) to the strongest (audits). It is possible to make a distinction between centralised (information duty and audits) and decentralised forms of monitoring (denouncing duty). A distinction should also be made between information duty and auditing, on the one hand, and denouncing the breach of CoCs by other platforms, on the other. The former mechanisms entail centralised monitoring by the self-regulatory organisation, whereas the latter involves decentralised monitoring by other industry members. Decentralised monitoring is expected to produce efficient outcomes in terms of detecting a breach, only in close-knit communities with limited membership. Both the costs of monitoring and free-riding problem increase with a broad membership.

French, Dutch and Nordic CoCs do not foresee any monitoring mechanisms. This does not exclude the possibility that such a mechanism is foreseen in other rules of association such as statutes. Only the German CoC foresees the information duty. Art. 4 of the Transparency Certificate Guidelines of the German CoC requires the platforms to provide information about the owners, the latest auditor's report, the data security officer and procedures in case of platform insolvency. This information is shared with a designated officer in the association, but it is not published externally or shared among the platforms.

Three CoCs foresee an obligation to denounce unlawful behaviour and non-compliance with the CoC. Article 15 of the UK Crowdfunding CoC describes and limits the denouncing obligation at the same time. The article states that the ability of platforms to denounce negative behaviour is limited by confidentiality obligations towards its users. Similarly, the Austrian CoC in Art. 14 ensures that deviations from the CoC are being brought to the attention of the Subcommittee of the Financial Intermediaries in the Chamber of Commerce. Since the Subcommittee of Financial Intermediaries is higher in the hierarchy than the Working Group for Crowdfunding Platforms in Austria, this provision entails a severe threat to the platform which breaches the CoC.

Audits are usually done by the associations themselves or by external agents. Four CoCs (European CoC, UK Crowdfunding CoC, UK Lending CoC, Estonian CoC) foresee audits and require the platform members to agree to be audited. The UK Lending CoC in Art 7 stipulates that a formal inquiry can result in an audit through the association – the audit is the consequence of an earlier notification of misconduct, submitted by a competitor of the platform. The Estonian CoC in Art. 11 of the Best Practices Guidelines stipulates that the label is reviewed once per year. The same is the case for the Transparency Certificate of the German Crowdfunding Association.

In sum, monitoring mechanisms are very diverse across crowdfunding markets. Except for the Austrian CoC, crowdfunding associations opted for a centralised system or mixed systems (in the United Kingdom). This is in line with a broad membership discussed earlier. Audits, as the most intrusive monitoring mechanism, are foreseen in a few markets. It is worth noting that European CoC, German Transparency Certificate, UK Lending CoC and Estonian CoC are also self-regulatory regimes with exclusive membership as discussed in subsection 2.2. This correlation suggests that, in a few cases, self-regulatory regimes are meant to serve as club signals. Other cases of weak monitoring support the “reputation commons” theory.

Rules on enforcement are another critical component of CoCs. As Buchanan (1965, p. 1965) points out, “the theory of clubs is […] a theory of optimal exclusion”. The exclusion devices must be in place to ensure that no one can benefit from club goods created through self-regulation without contributing as a club member. Clubs without means to withdraw or suspend membership are not efficient in enforcing the rules. Similarly, the “coerced” theory lies on the premise that the association can impose sanctions on non-complying industry members.

The paper finds that four (UK Crowdfunding CoC, UK Lending CoC, French CoC and Estonian CoC) out of nine CoCs contain membership withdrawal or suspension clauses. The procedures for a suspension or withdrawal of membership are quite diverse. The UK Crowdfunding CoC in Article 16 delegates the authority to the directors of the association. The UK Lending CoC in Art. 7 allows for the suspension of the membership only after a formal inquiry and hearing of the member. The Estonian CoC in Art 11 2nd paragraph foresees the expulsion of members if they do not comply with the best practice guidelines and that no compensation can be retrieved from the association. It is important to note that enforcement of the rules is stronger if it entails a label that can be withdrawn, making the expulsion from an association visible to investors as well.

Another related mechanism of enforcement is a dispute resolution mechanism. A dispute can arise either between members and the association or between members. Four (European CoC, UK Lending CoC, French CoC, Estonian CoC) out of nine CoCs foresee a dispute resolution mechanism. The European CoC in Art 2.5 describes the mechanism for a dispute resolution between members, motivating that “parties will always seek a negotiated solution”. The members of the European association can also appoint an external mediator. The UK Lending CoC Article 7 of the Rules outlines a similar complaint procedure. Complaints by members can be resolved without a formal inquiry, but if a significant breach is detected, then a formal inquiry will be launched, which can result in expulsion from the association. The French CoC in Art 11 is unique insofar it stipulates that the French Association can become a mediator for disputes between platforms and between platforms and investors or between platforms and projects. Art 10 of the Best Practice Guidelines of the Estonian CoC stipulates that the association will publish dispute cases.

Overall, the strong enforcement mechanisms are foreseen in less than half of CoCs discussed. In relation to findings of the prevalence of inclusive membership and weak monitoring from previous subsections, the theory of “reputation commons” has the most explanatory power. However, once again case examples such as Estonian CoC and UK Lending CoC which, in addition to restrictive membership clauses and strong monitoring, have strong enforcement mechanisms in place bring evidence for the “club goods” theory.

4.4 Content of codes of conduct

The following overview (Tables VII and VIII) of substantial rules contained in CoCs in Europe, and the coherent systematisation of provisions, may facilitate the future in-depth study and cross-country comparisons. Due to a large number of provisions appearing under different wordings and sporadically in several CoCs, this section will not indicate where provisions appear and how they differ. Such an extensive analysis merits a deeper reflection on the underlying regulation in each country, which is beyond the framework of this paper.

Beyond the provisions pertaining to the relation between platform and associations, the paper identified three broad categories of substantial provisions in CoCs:

  1. Provisions related to the transparency of platforms' behaviour;

  2. Provisions related to the business conduct of platforms;

  3. Provisions related to the protection of investors (beyond transparency).

Even though transparency, business conduct and investor protection relate to each other in manifold ways, the list of provisions in Tables VII and VIII allow a first glimpse of the topics covered in CoC.

The main concern of both regulators and industry participants are potential market failures due to information asymmetries. Platforms compete not only in terms of fees but also in terms of the quality of their service.

As discussed in subsection 2.2, important aspects of platforms' operation are unobservable by their customers. Screening and selection of projects are often not made transparent. Contracts between platforms and project owners are not made public. The outcome of platforms' due diligence of financial documents and legal structure of the projects is not always published. Management of conflicts of interest is not easily discerned for individual investors. Services in the post-investment stage and overall performance of projects' cannot easily be identified by investors.

All CoCs contain a mixture of rules which increase transparency and rules that establish standards of service quality. The systematisation of provisions contained in CoCs sheds light on services which platforms choose to compete on. For instance, greater transparency is often required with respect to fees charged, project selection criteria and platforms' due diligence. For these services, in the platforms' view, information remedy is sufficient. On the contrary, for some services platforms choose to regulate quality directly. For instance, rules of business conduct are of this type. Some of the provisions of CoCs, such as anti-money laundering or data security, are already required by the law. The rationale for including them into a CoC is to provide additional monitoring and enforcing mechanism.

While the primary purpose of CoCs is to reduce information asymmetries between platforms and their clients, many of the provisions of CoCs indirectly reduce the information advantage of project owners over investors. This is done through mandating platforms to have a mechanism in place to induce greater disclosure by project owners. Trust in the platforms then translates into trust in the projects (Moysidou and Hausberg, 2019). In this way, platforms indirectly “communicate the legitimacy of crowdfunding ventures” (Lehner and Harrer, 2019, p. 85).

The content analysis of the provisions of CoCs does not allow to decide whether “coerced” theories are more plausible than “voluntary” theories. The provisions which restate the obligation to comply with state laws and regulations already in place support the explanatory power of “voluntary” self-regulation theories, since “coerced CoCs” would focus on newly developed provisions in order to defer or stifle regulation.

In the final section, the paper will discuss how to extend the research of the CoCs based on an analysis of the provisions.

5. Conclusion and implications for further research

The paper has discussed the emergence of CoCs in the European crowdfunding market. Based on a systematic overview of CoCs in different European jurisdictions, including transnational efforts, the analysis reveals that CoCs are a common form of coordination and cooperation between competitors. The question as to what explains the prevalence of self-regulation in the crowdfunding market has to be addressed by looking at existing economic theories on self-regulation developed for different industries. The paper builds upon existing theories of self-regulation to provide a theoretical framework for the comparative study of CoCs in crowdfunding markets. In particular, the paper elaborates how the institutional design of CoCs can help understand their economic purpose.

At the outset, different characteristics of crowdfunding markets can support two competing theoretical frameworks for the emergence of self-regulation: theories of “coerced” and “voluntary” self-regulation. Within “voluntary” theories of self-regulation, the paper distinguishes between self-regulation, which serves as a club-like institution to signal quality, and self-regulation, whose purpose is to provide “reputation commons” to industry members.

Institutional design features of CoCs analysed in the subsequent sections mainly provide support for one of the “voluntary” theories of self-regulation. The findings which relate to inclusiveness of CoCs illustrate that most of the CoCs opted for a broad membership. In relation to weak monitoring and enforcement mechanisms found in several CoCs, platforms are mainly concerned with ensuring minimum standards that all members of the industry will adhere to, thus, ensuring that “reputation commons” are protected. In addition, members of CoCs de facto group around different business models, which implies that reputation spillovers are not significant between different types of crowdfunding. However, institutional features of a few CoCs, the Estonian example being the most prominent, clearly indicate club-like features of some self-regulatory regimes.

The paper also provides a first systematic overview of substantial rules of CoCs in crowdfunding. Provisions of CoCs are surprisingly elaborate and detailed, suggesting that self-regulatory efforts in crowdfunding go far beyond general principles found in CoCs of other industries. All the provisions found in different CoCs are grouped into three categories: rules related to transparency, investor protection and business conduct. The analysis reveals that platforms emphasised provisions related to transparency. While this can underpin the argument that platforms try to pre-empt government from regulating quality standards (“Coerced” self-regulation), a more detailed analysis shows that many provisions simply reinforce some of the existing regulations, adding a second level of enforcement. These provisions provide further support for “voluntary” theories of self-regulation. The overview of substantial rules of CoCs also illuminates potential sources of market failure in the crowdfunding market through lenses of platforms.

Although the paper provides the most support for the theory of “reputation commons”, it does not imply that “coerced” theories of self-regulation should be entirely abandoned. For one reason, regulatory, economic and social environments of different crowdfunding markets can create different incentives for platforms. These factors are also likely to bear importance for the institutional design of CoCs beyond the overarching purpose of self-regulation discussed in this paper.

In order to deepen this analysis, further research would be necessary to analyse in detail the regulatory frameworks in each country and discuss the interaction between statutory provisions and those contained in CoCs. Concerning the observed practice of revising CoCs, further research is needed to assess whether and to what extent the content of CoCs affects the choice of rules of subsequent statutory regulations. Other country-specific factors, in particular, deepness and liquidity of financial markets, as well as other institutional factors, are expected to strongly influence the development of crowdfunding industry and dynamics of self-regulatory rules. In some instances, crowdfunding CoCs developed with the help of associations of conventional financial industries, potentially creating path dependence in terms of institutional design of CoCs. Further research should also assess patterns of diffusion of CoCs provisions across different jurisdictions, since some anecdotal evidence suggests that a few crowdfunding associations found inspiration for their CoC in ready-made solutions in other countries.

The analysis of substantial provisions of CoCs also requires further attention concerning two aspects. Firstly, it is necessary to discuss the differences in substantial provisions of CoCs in various countries and explain how these relate to the economic purpose of CoCs discussed in this paper. Secondly, it is useful to discern reasons for both the inclusion and exclusion of specific provisions that were discussed among stakeholders in the drafting process. Qualitative interviewing of key platforms can provide further insights.

Another significant extension of this paper would be assessing the actual implementation of CoCs. Given that many of the provisions are very specific and partially verifiable, it is necessary to check whether platforms implement and follow these rules. Such findings bear important implications for the regulators worldwide who are struggling to find an optimal level of regulatory intervention. In relation to this, at the macro level, further research is needed to estimate what is the effect of self-regulation on the level of trust in the crowdfunding industry and consequently, market developments.

The discussion of CoCs provided in this paper can be informative for crowdfunding associations worldwide. The summary of substantial provisions supports crowdfunding associations planning to introduce a self-regulatory regime. The paper provides guidance as to which areas of self-regulation and specific regulatory solutions are important to the crowdfunding industry. The paper highlights the necessity to align the institutional design and the content of the CoC. Depending on the goal of a CoC, the institutional design and the content of the CoC should mirror each other. Principle-based provisions are better tailored to a more inclusive CoC, whereas specific CoC obligations can be effectively enforced through a more club-like institutional design of a CoC.

Theoretical framework for crowdfunding CoCs

Institutional dimensionCoerced theoryVoluntary theory
Club goodsReputation commons
OriginAnticipating state regulationsAnticipating or reacting to existing state regulationsAnticipating or reacting to existing state regulations
InclusivenessInclusive membershipExclusive membershipInclusive membership
Enforcement and MonitoringStrong and centralisedStrong and centralised/decentralisedWeak and centralised
ContentCreating new rulesCreating new rules and/or restating existing rulesCreating new rules and/or restating existing rules

Overview of CoCs found by desk research and outreach to associations

Internet search (7)Outreach to associations (5)
Included in the sample (9)UK Crowdfunding CoC
UK Lending CoC
Dutch CoC
European CoC
Nordic CoC
Austrian CoC
German CoC
French CoC
Estonian CoC
Not included in the sample (3)CAPS CoC
Crowdfund Port CoC
Spanish CoC

Example of content analysis of Coc provisions

Level 1 Provision purposeLevel 2 Provision contextLevel 3 Provision dutyProvision text and translated text (from the French CoC)
Investor ProtectionPost-InvestmentLabel
Limitation of Losses
Reformulated Text
Investors Losses are limited to their original investment
Original Text
§6 […] En tout état de cause, le financeur ne peut subir de pertes sur une platforme au-delà de son investissement initial. […]
Translation:
§6 […] In any event, the funder may not incur losses on a platform beyond its initial investment. […]

First-level and second-level clustering

First level clusteringSecond level clustering
FrameworkPurpose
Inclusiveness
Monitoring and Enforcement
TransparencyPlatform-Specific Transparency (Pre-Investment)
Platform-Specific Transparency (Post-Investment)
Project-Specific Transparency (Pre-Investment)
Project-Specific Transparency (Post-Investment)
Investor ProtectionInvestor-Protection (Pre-Investment)
Investor-Protection (Post-Investment)
Business ConductGood Governance
Conflict of Interest
Detection of Unlawful Behaviour
Transactions
Data Security and IT
Cease of Operation
Competition

Overview of existing CoCs

Name of the associationCountryCode of conduct and the denotation in this studyYear of adoptionCrowdfunding regulatory framework
UK Crowdfunding Association (UKCFA)United KingdomUK Crowdfunding CoC20131 April 2014
Peer2Peer Finance Association (P2PFA)United KingdomUK Lending CoC20131 April 2014 (revised rules applicable as of 9 December 2019)
Financement Participatif France (FPF)FranceFrench CoC20141 October 2014
Bundesverband Crowdfunding (BVCF)GermanyGerman CoC201610 July 2015
Wirtschaftskammer Österreich – Fachverband Finanzdienstleister – Arbeitsgruppe Crowdfunding (WKO)AustriaAustrian CoC201614 August 2015
Nederlands Crowdfunding (NF)NetherlandsDutch CoC20171 April 2016
Finance Estonia (FE)EstoniaEstonian CoC2016X
European Crowdfunding Network (ECN)EuropeEuropean CoC2015Proposal by the European Commission in 2018. Adoption by the European Parliament in 2019. Adoption by the European Council still open.
Nordic Crowdfunding Alliance (NCA)Norway, Sweden, Denmark, Finland, IcelandNordic CoC20171 September 2016 (only in Finland)

Overview of monitoring mechanisms

CoCNoneInformation dutyDenouncing dutyAudits
European CoC x
UK Crowdfunding CoC xx
UK Lending CoC xx
French CoCx
Austrian CoC x
German CoC X
Dutch CoCx
Estonian CoC x
Nordic CoCx

Transparency and investor protection provisions

TransparencyPlatform-Specific Transparency (Pre-Investment)Clear InformationTerms and conditions are written in a clear way
Project Selection CriteriaPlatforms state their selection criteria
Disclosure RequirementsPlatforms state which information they require from project owners to disclose
Due Diligence/Verification of InformationPlatforms state how they verify the information from projects
Platforms publish their role in the verification of data
Fees and ChargesPlatforms state how they are remunerated
Platform-Specific Transparency (Post-Investment)Statistics and Market DevelopmentPlatforms provide data about their activity
Full List of Investment Projects
Full Loan Book
Platforms provide a complete overview of all projects on their platform. Platforms do not hide unsuccessful projects
Project-Specific Transparency (Pre-Investment)Clear and Unbiased InformationProjects display potential returns and risks of projects in a clear manner
Mandatory Disclosure of Project InformationProjects provide minimum information (either mandated by platform, law and/or association)
Platforms publish minimum requirements for information of the projects towards the investors
Project-Specific Transparency (Post-Investment)Scenario AnalysisPlatforms test the performance of their investment/loan portfolio under adverse scenarios
Individual Portfolio AnalysisPlatforms analyse how the portfolio of an individual investor behaves and informs him about it
Ongoing Disclosure of ProjectsProjects report about their activities after the campaign
Individual investor's fund informationPlatforms provide information to investors on where their funds are in each moment
Investor ProtectionInvestor Protection (Pre-Investment)Risk WarningsPlatforms provide risk warnings to investors
Tax Regime InformationPlatforms give information about the applicable tax treatment
Investor Protection (Post-Investment)Cooling-Off PeriodInvestors can withdraw their investment during the funding period
Limitation of LossesInvestors losses are limited to their original investment
Dispute resolutionPlatforms maintain a mechanism for solving conflicts between projects and investors and between platforms and investors

Business conduct provisions

Business ConductGood GovernancePermitted ActivitiesPlatforms do not act as an investment firm or bank and do not offer investment advice unless authorised
Operation of PlatformPlatforms ensure that they are operated in a reliable manner
Staff and ManagementPlatforms hire competent staff
Conflict of InterestConflict of Interest ManagementPlatforms manage conflict of interest between platform staff and investors, the platform as an entity and investors. Platforms publish conflict of interest if they occur
Non-Discrimination of InvestorsPlatforms treat all investors equally
Non-Discrimination of ProjectsPlatforms treat all projects equally
Project Owners InformationProjects have the right to be informed about rejection or acceptance.
Projects owners have no right to be accepted on a platform
Detection of Unlawful behaviourDetection of FraudPlatforms have a mechanism to detect fraud
Anti-Money-Laundering ActivitiesPlatforms have a mechanism to detect money-laundering practices
TransactionsSegregation of FundsPlatforms ensure that the funds of investors are separate from the operational accounts of the respective platform
Security of TransactionsPlatforms ensure that the funds of the investor reach the desired project
Transfer of FundsPlatforms transfer funds to projects after rules of investment are triggered
Data Security and
IT Structure
Security of User InformationPlatforms ensure that user information is kept safe
Security of IT SystemPlatforms ensure that the security of the IT system is guaranteed
Security of Project DataPlatforms ensure that commercially sensitive information of projects is secure and remains confidential
Cease of OperationProcess for winding down operationsPlatforms have a process for winding down their operation
Ownership of InvestmentsPlatforms ensure that investors retain ownership of their investments
CompetitionFair MarketingPlatforms ensure that sales and marketing activity complies with existing laws and regulation
Healthy CompetitionPlatforms promote healthy competition; unfair competitive practices are not accepted
Competitors' TrademarksPlatforms do not compete on competitors' trademarks in marketing

Notes

1.

Credence goods or credence qualities are “those which, although worthwhile cannot be evaluated in normal use” (Darby and Karni, 1973, p. 69–69). They are different from search qualities, which can be assessed before a purchase, and experience qualities, which can be assessed after the purchase. The distinction between search and experience goods was originally made by Nelson (1970).

2.

In the last years, crowdfunding markets have seen substantial technological change, especially concerning the setup and business models of the platforms. For instance, crowdfunding platforms have introduced new mechanisms for determining prices of assets and creating secondary markets. Platforms have also introduced new technologies, such as blockchain-based mechanisms of intermediation through Initial Coin Offerings (ICOs) and Security Token Offerings (STOs). All of these changes have triggered much regulatory uncertainty.

3.

The website layout of crowdfunding platforms was popularized by reward-based crowdfunding platforms, such as Kickstarter and Indiegogo. It can be found on many equity- and lending-based crowdfunding platforms as well. This “look and feel” of crowdfunding platforms is not governed by a standard set by market players. The paper does not aim to explain the emergence of such a technological standard. Yet, as can be seen in the list of provisions, the CoCs do not mention the website design.

4.

Under crowdfunding regulatory framework, the paper considers only laws and regulations that are tailored to crowdfunding activity (bespoke regimes), notwithstanding that crowdfunding can trigger the application of other rules in relation to the provision of financial services.

5.

Some crowdfunding associations (in the United Kingdom, Germany, France, Netherlands, Nordic countries) allow the associated membership of companies which are not platforms, such as law firms, payment providers, banks or universities. However, CoCs do not apply to the associated members. In contrast, the French CoC, for instance, specifically states that white-label-software providers are also covered by CoCs.

References

Akerlof, G.A. (1978), “The market for ‘lemons’: quality uncertainty and the market mechanism”, Uncertainty in Economics, Elsevier, pp. 235-251.

Aldrich, H.E. and Fiol, C.M. (1994), “Fools rush in? the institutional context of industry creation”, Academy of Management Review, Vol. 19, pp. 645-670.

Armour, J. and Enriques, L. (2018), “The promise and perils of crowdfunding: between corporate finance and consumer contracts: the promise and perils of crowdfunding”, The Modern Law Review, Vol. 81, pp. 51-84.

Barnett, M.L. (2006), “Finding a working balance between competitive and communal strategies”, Journal of Management Studies, Vol. 43 No. 8, pp. 1753-1773.

Belcher, A. (1996), “The invention, innovation and diffusion of self-regulation in corporate governance”, Northern Ireland Law Quarterly, Vol. 47, pp. 322-334.

Belleflamme, P., Lambert, T. and Schwienbacher, A. (2014), “Crowdfunding: tapping the right crowd”, Journal of Business Venturing, Vol. 29, pp. 585-609.

Benson, B.L. (1988), “Legal evolution in primitive societies”, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (JITE)/Zeitschrift Für Die Gesamte Staatswissenschaft, pp. 772-788.

Black, J. (1996), “Constitutionalising self-regulation”, The Modern Law Review, Vol. 59, pp. 24-55.

Blohm, I., Gallen, Universität St. and Wenzlaff, K. (Eds) (2013), Crowdfunding-Studie 2013/2014: Analyse, Perspektiven und Erfolgsfaktoren innovativer Unternehmens- und Projektfinanzierungsformen, epubli, Berlin.

Bowen, F. (2019), “Marking their own homework: the pragmatic and moral legitimacy of industry self-regulation”, Journal of Business Ethics, Vol. 156, pp. 257-272.

Buchanan, J.M. (1965), “An economic theory of clubs”, Economica, Vol. 32, pp. 1-14.

Corbin, J.M. and Strauss, A.L. (2015), Basics of Qualitative Research: Techniques and Procedures for Developing Grounded Theory, 4th ed., SAGE, Los Angeles.

CrowdfundPort, I.C.E. (2016), “Code of conduct”, available at: https://www.interreg-central.eu/Content.Node/CROWD-FUND-PORT/CFP-D.T1.1.2-Code-of-conduct.pdf.

Cumming, D. and Hornuf, L. (2018), The Economics of Crowdfunding, Palgrave Macmillan, London, UK.

Darby, M.R. and Karni, E. (1973), “Free competition and the optimal amount of fraud”, The Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 16, pp. 67-88.

Dingwall, R. and Fenn, P. (1987), “‘A respectable profession’? sociological and economic perspectives on the regulation of professional services”, International Review of Law and Economics, Vol. 7, pp. 51-64.

Dixit, A. (2009), “Governance institutions and economic activity”, The American Economic Review, Vol. 99, pp. 5-24.

European Commission (2018), Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council on European Crowdfunding Service Providers (ECSP) for Business, Brussels.

European Parliament (2019), Legislative Resolution Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council on European Crowdfunding Service Providers (ECSP) for Business, Brussels.

Gehrig, T. and Jost, P.-J. (1995), “Quacks, lemons, and self regulation: a welfare analysis”, Journal of Regulatory Economics, Vol. 7, pp. 309-325.

Gilbert, D.U., Rasche, A. and Waddock, S. (2011), “Accountability in a global economy: the emergence of international accountability standards”, Business Ethics Quarterly, Vol. 21, pp. 23-44.

Gorton, G. and Mullineaux, D.J. (1987), “The Joint production of confidence: endogenous regulation and nineteenth century commercial-bank clearinghouses”, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 19, p. 457.

Gunningham, N. and Rees, J. (1997), “Industry selfregulation: an institutional perspective”, Law & Policy, Vol. 19 No. 4, pp. 363-414.

Haas, P., Blohm, I. and Leimeister, J.M. (2014), “An empirical taxonomy of crowdfunding intermediaries”, in M. Myers and D. Straub (Eds), Proceedings of the 35th International Conference on Information Systems, Auckland, pp. 1-18.

Hemer, J., Schneider, U., Dornbusch, F. and Frey, S. (2011), Crowdfunding und andere Formen informeller Mikrofinanzierung in der Projekt-und Innovationsfinanzierung, Fraunhofer Verlag.

Howard, J., Nash, J. and Ehrenfeld, J. (2000), “Standard or smokescreen? implementation of a voluntary environmental code”, California Management Review, Vol. 42, pp. 63-82.

Jegelevičiūtė, S. and Valančienė, L. (2015), “Comparative analysis of the ways crowdfunding is promoted”, Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences, Vol. 213, pp. 268-274.

Kshetri, N. (2015), “Success of crowd-based online technology in fundraising: an institutional perspective”, Journal of International Management, Vol. 21, pp. 100-116.

Lehner, O.M. and Harrer, T. (2019), “Crowdfunding revisited: a neo-institutional field-perspective”, Venture Capital, Vol. 21, pp. 75-96.

Massolution (2015), “2015CF Crowdfunding industry report [crowdfunding industry report]”, available at: http://reports.crowdsourcing.org/index.php?route=product/product&product_id=54.

Maxwell, J.W., Lyon, T.P. and Hackett, S.C. (2000), “Self-regulation and social welfare: the political economy of corporate environmentalism”, The Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 43, pp. 583-618.

Moysidou, K. and Hausberg, J.P. (2019), “In crowdfunding we trust: a trust-building model in lending crowdfunding”, Journal of Small Business Management, Vol. 0, pp. 1-33.

Nelson, P. (1970), “Information and consumer behavior”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 78, pp. 311-329.

Ogus, A. (1995), “Rethinking self-regulation”, Oxford Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 15, p. 97.

Philipsen, N.J. (2012), “Regulation of accountants”, in Van Den Bergh, R. and Paces, A.M. (Eds), Encyclopedia of Law and Economics: Regulation and Economics, Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, pp. 715-742.

Posner, R.A. (1980), “A theory of primitive society, with special reference to law”, The Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 23, pp. 1-53.

Prakash, A. and Potoski, M. (2007), “Collective action through voluntary environmental programs: a club theory perspective: prakash/potoski: collective action through voluntary environmental programs”, Policy Studies Journal, Vol. 35, pp. 773-792.

Rau, P.R. (2017), “Law, trust, and the development of crowdfunding”, available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2989056.

Schwarcz, S.L. (2002), “Private ordering”, Nw. UL Rev, Vol. 97, pp. 319-350.

Schwienbacher, A. (2014), “Crowdinvesting in the Netherlands: market analysis, securities regulation and policy options”, DSF Policy Paper 48, pp. 1-20, available at: http://docplayer.net/36158729-Crowdinvesting-in-the-netherlands-market-analysissecurities-regulation-and-policy-options.html.

Stefanadis, C. (2003), “Self-regulation, innovation, and the financial industry”, Journal of Regulatory Economics, Vol. 23, pp. 5-25.

Surowiecki, J. (2004), The Wisdom of Crowds: Why the Many are Smarter than the Few and How Collective Wisdom Shapes Business, Economies, Societies, and Nations. Doubleday Books, New York, NY.

Turan, S.S. (2015), “Financial innovation - crowdfunding: friend or foe?”, Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences, Vol. 195, pp. 353-362.

Van den Bergh, R. (2004), “Towards efficient self-regulation in markets for professional services”, European Competition Law Annual, 2006, p. 155.

Wenzlaff, K. (2019), Developing a Policy Framework for Emerging Crowdfunding Ecosystems, ORF Policy Briefs, Vol. 12, pp. 1-12.

Williams, A.D. (2004), An Economic Theory of Self-Regulation, London School of Economic, Department of Government.

Yin, R.K. (2014), Case Study Research: Design and Methods, 5th ed., SAGE, Los Angeles.

Yue, L.Q. and Ingram, P. (2012), “Industry self-regulation as a solution to the reputation commons problem: the case of the New York clearing house association”, in Barnett, M. L. and Pollock, T. G. (Eds), The Oxford Handbook of Corporate Reputation, available at: http://faculty.marshall.usc.edu/Lori-Yue/documents/publications/book_and_conference/Banks%27_Reputation_Commons.pdf.

Ziegler, T., Shneor, R., Garvey, K., Wenzlaff, K., Yerolemou, N., Rui, H. and Zhang, B. (2018), Expanding horizons: the 3rd European alternative finance industry report, Cambridge Centre for Alternative Finance, Cambridge, available at: https://www.jbs.cam.ac.uk/fileadmin/user_upload/research/centres/alternativefinance/downloads/2018-02-ccaf-exp-horizons.pdf.

Ziegler, T., Shneor, R., Wenzlaff, K., Odorovic, A., Johanson, D., Hao, R. and Ryll, L. (2019), Shifting paradigms: the 4th European alternative finance benchmarking report, Cambridge Centre for Alternative Finance, Cambridge, available at: https://www.jbs.cam.ac.uk/fileadmin/user_upload/research/centres/alternativefinance/downloads/2019-05-4th-european-alternative-finance-benchmarking-industry-reportshifting-paradigms.pdf.

Appendix–Code of Conducts

Asociación Espanola de Crowdfunding (2018), “Guía de Buenas prácticas”, available at: http://www.spaincrowdfunding.org/wa_files/Guia-de-buenas-pra_CC_81cticas.pdf.

Bundesverband Crowdfunding (2016a), “Reporting Guidelines für Crowdfunding-Plattformen im Bundesverband Crowdfunding e.V”, available at: https://www.bundesverband-crowdfunding.de/reporting-guidelines-fuer-crowdfunding-plattformen-im-bundesverband-crowdfunding-e-v/.

Bundesverband Crowdfunding (2016b), “Verhaltenskodex für Crowdfunding-Plattformen”, available at: https://www.bundesverband-crowdfunding.de/verhaltenskodex-fuer-crowdfunding-plattformen-im-bundesverband-crowdfunding-e-v/.

Bundesverband Crowdfunding (2019), “Transparenzsiegel”, available at: https://www.bundesverband-crowdfunding.de/transparenzsiegel/.

CrowdfundPort, I.C.E. (2016), “Code of conduct”, available at: https://www.interreg-central.eu/Content.Node/CROWD-FUND-PORT/CFP-D.T1.1.2-Code-of-conduct.pdf.

European Crowdfunding Network (2015), “Code of conduct”, available at: https://eurocrowd.org/membership/code-of-conduct/.

Finance Estonia and Deloitte Legal Estonia (2016a), “Finance Estonia - best Practice for crowdfunding platforms”, available at: http://www.financeestonia.eu/wp-content/uploads/2016/02/Crowdfunding-Best-Practice.pdf.

Finance Estonia and Deloitte Legal Estonia (2016b), “Finance Estonia - report Form for best practice crowdfunding”, available at: http://financeestonia.eu/wp-content/uploads/2016/02/Best-Practice-Report.pdf.

Financement Participatif France (2014), “Code de déontologie”, available at: http://financeparticipative.org/wp-content/uploads/2015/03/FPF-Code-déontologie-_-Avril_2014.pdf.

Financement Participatif France (2016), “Code de déontologie”, available at: http://financeparticipative.org/wp-content/uploads/2016/04/FPF-Code-déontologie_avril-2016.pdf.

Nederland Crowdfunding (2017), “Gedragscode”, available at: http://startcrowdfunding.nl/about.

Nordic Crowdfunding Association (2017), “Code of ethics”, available at: http://www.nordic-crowdfunding.com/about.php#anchor3.

Peer-to-Peer Finance Association (2013), “Operating principles”, available at: http://p2pfa.info/wp-content/uploads/2014/05/P2PFA-Operating-PrinciplesV020713.pdf.

Peer-to-Peer Finance Association (2015), “Operating principles”, available at: http://p2pfa.info/wp-content/uploads/2015/09/Operating-Principals-vfinal.pdf.

Peer-to-Peer Finance Association (2018), “Operating principles”, available at: https://p2pfa.org.uk/wp-content/uploads/2018/06/2018.06.27-Operating-Principles-1.pdf.

UK Crowdfunding Association (2018), “Operating principles”, available at: https://www.ukcfa.org.uk/join-us/code-of-conduct/.

WKÖ Wirtschaftskammer Österreich, F.F. (2016), “Standesregeln für Crowdfunding Plattform”, available at: https://www.wko.at/branchen/sbg/information-consulting/finanzdienstleister/standes-und-ausuebungsregeln-ci.html.

Acknowledgements

The authors wish to express gratitude to our colleagues and mentors at the University of Hamburg, Professor Dr. Wolf-Georg Ringe and Professor Dr. Sebastian Spath, both have provided guidance and very valuable feedback for this paper.

The authors wish to acknowledge the following persons and institutions for their help with the content of the paper as well as data collection process:

- the University of Cambridge Centre for Alternative Finance

- the European Alternative Finance Network of the University of Utrecht

- the EU-Project CrowdFundPort

- the representatives of Crowdfunding associations

- the representatives of platforms and other Crowdfunding experts

Comments were also provided by conference participants at the conference of the German Law and Economics Association, at the Conference at the Spanish Law and Economics Association, the Conference of the European Alternative Finance Center in Utrecht, the conference for PhD Students in Innovation Studies in Hamburg.

The research of Ana Odorović is supported by the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft (DFG) and the University of Hamburg through a scholarship at the Graduate School in Law and Economics at the Institute of Law and Economics of the University of Hamburg.

The research of Karsten Wenzlaff at the Graduate School at the Faculty for Socioeconomics at the University of Hamburg is not funded by an external source. He studies part-time and he is grateful to the European Commission, the Interreg Central Europe programme and his clients to allow him the academic pursuit of academic questions in the context of his work.

We would like to thank the Editors of the Baltic Journal of Management as well as the Guest Editors of the Special Edition for their very helpful comments. We are also grateful for valuable advice from the reviewers of this paper.

None of the above persons and institutions are responsible for the content of this paper. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors only. All remaining errors are our own.

Corresponding author

Karsten Wenzlaff is the corresponding author and can be contacted at: karsten.wenzlaff@uni-hamburg.de

About the authors

Ana Odorović is a member of the DFG Graduate School in Law and Economics at the University of Hamburg and lecturer at University of Belgrade Faculty of Law. She is also a research affiliate at the Cambridge Centre for Alternative Finance, Judge Business School. In 2018, she was a visiting researcher at the University of Oxford. She holds an LL.M. degree in business law from the Pantheon-Assas University (Paris 2) and a master’s degree in Economics from the University of Belgrade.

Karsten Wenzlaff is an alternative finance researcher at the University of Hamburg at the Chair for Digital Markets. His research interests are Civic Crowdfunding for Public Goods, Corporate Crowdfunding and Regulatory Competitiveness in Crowdfunding Ecosystems, especially in Central and Eastern Europe through the project Crowdfundport. Karsten has published reports on the European and German Crowdfunding Ecosystems since 2010. He is a member of the European Crowdfunding Stakeholder Forum of the European Commission and a member of the University of Cambridge Alternative Finance Industry Leadership Council, and he edits the Alternative Finance Benchmarking Report. He is an Affiliate Researcher with the European Alternative Finance Center of the University of Utrecht. Karsten Wenzlaff has received an Mphil Cantab in International Relations from the University of Cambridge. He teaches at the University of Hamburg and the University for Applied Sciences in Bremen. Karsten Wenzlaff is the corresponding author and can be contacted at: karsten.wenzlaff@uni-hamburg.de

Related articles