1932

Abstract

Milton Friedman argued that giving parents freedom to choose schools would improve education. His argument was simple and compelling because it extended results from markets for consumer goods to education. We review the evidence, which yields surprisingly mixed results on Friedman's prediction. A key reason is that households often seem to choose schools based on their absolute achievement rather than their value added. We show that this can be rational in a model based on three ingredients that economists have highlighted since Friedman worked on the issue. First, education is an investment into human capital. Second, labor markets can feature wage premia: Individuals of a given skill level may receive higher wages if they match to more productive firms. Third, distance influences school choice and the placements that schools produce. These factors imply that choice alone is too crude a mechanism to ensure the effective provision of schooling.

Loading

Article metrics loading...

/content/journals/10.1146/annurev-economics-080218-030402
2019-08-02
2024-04-24
Loading full text...

Full text loading...

/deliver/fulltext/economics/11/1/annurev-economics-080218-030402.html?itemId=/content/journals/10.1146/annurev-economics-080218-030402&mimeType=html&fmt=ahah

Literature Cited

  1. Abdulkadiroglu A, Agarwal N, Pathak P 2017a. The welfare effects of coordinated assignment: evidence from the New York City high school match. Am. Econ. Rev. 107:3635–89
    [Google Scholar]
  2. Abdulkadiroglu A, Angrist J, Hull P, Pathak P 2016. Charters without lotteries: testing takeovers in New Orleans and Boston. Am. Econ. Rev. 106:1878–920
    [Google Scholar]
  3. Abdulkadiroglu A, Angrist J, Pathak P 2014. The elite illusion: achievement effects at Boston and New York exam schools. Econometrica 82:137–96
    [Google Scholar]
  4. Abdulkadiroglu A, Pathak P, Schellenberg J, Walters C 2017b. Do parents value school effectiveness? Unpublished manuscript Duke Univ. Durham, NC:
  5. Abdulkadiroglu A, Pathak P, Walters CR 2018. Free to choose: Can school choice reduce student achievement. Am. Econ. J. Appl. Econ. 10175–206
    [Google Scholar]
  6. Abowd JM, Kramarz F, Margolis DN 1999. High wage workers and high wage firms. Econometrica 67:251–333
    [Google Scholar]
  7. Acemoglu D, Autor D 2011. Skills, tasks and technologies: implications for employment and earnings. Handbook of Labor Economics 4 O Ashenfelter, D Card1043–171 Amsterdam: Elsevier
    [Google Scholar]
  8. Aguirre J 2018. How can progressive vouchers help the poor benefit from school choice? Evidence from the Chilean voucher system Tech. Rep., Teach. Coll., Columbia Univ., New York
  9. Ajayi K 2014. Does school quality improve student performance? New evidence from Ghana Unpublished manuscript, Boston Univ.
  10. Altonji JG, Pierret CR 2001. Employer learning and statistical discrimination. Q. J. Econ. 116:313–50
    [Google Scholar]
  11. Angrist J, Bettinger E, Bloom E, Kremer M, King E 2002. The effect of school vouchers on students: evidence from Colombia. Am. Econ. Rev. 92:1535–58
    [Google Scholar]
  12. Angrist J, Bettinger E, Kremer M 2006. Long-term consequences of secondary school vouchers: evidence from administrative records in Colombia. Am. Econ. Rev. 96:3847–62
    [Google Scholar]
  13. Araujo MC, Carneiro P, Cruz-Aguayo Y, Schady N 2016. Teacher quality and learning outcomes in kindergarten. Q. J. Econ. 131:1415–53
    [Google Scholar]
  14. Arcidiacono P, Lovenheim M 2016. Affirmative action and the quality-fit tradeoff. J. Econ. Lit. 54:3–51
    [Google Scholar]
  15. Athey S, Stern S 1998. An empirical framework for testing theories about complementarity in organizational design NBER Work. Pap. 6600
  16. Autor D, Dorn D, Katz LF, Patterson C, Van Reenen J 2017. The fall of the labor share and the rise of superstar firms NBER Work. Pap. 23396
  17. Autor D, Levy F, Murname RJ 2003. The skill content of recent technological change: an empirical exploration. Q. J. Econ. 118:1279–334
    [Google Scholar]
  18. Autor DH 2014. Skills, education, and the rise of earnings inequality among the ‘other 99 percent’. Science 344:843–51
    [Google Scholar]
  19. Autor DH, Katz LF, Kearny MS 2006. The polarization of the U.S. labor market. Am. Econ. Rev. 96:189–94
    [Google Scholar]
  20. Autor DH, Katz LF, Kearny MS 2008. Trends in U.S. wage inequality: revising the revisionists. Rev. Econ. Stat. 90:300–23
    [Google Scholar]
  21. Avery CN, Glickman ME, Hoxby CM, Metrick A 2013. A revealed preference ranking of US colleges and universities. Q. J. Econ. 128:425–67
    [Google Scholar]
  22. Banerjee A 2007. Inside the machine: toward a new development economics. Boston Rev. 32:12–18
    [Google Scholar]
  23. Barrow L, Sartain L, de la Torre M 2017. The role of selective high schools in equalizing educational outcomes: using place-based affirmative action to estimate heterogeneous effect by neighborhood socioeconomic status Unpublished manuscript, Fed. Reserve Bank Chicago
  24. Bayer P, Ferreira F, McMillan R 2007. A unified framework for measuring preferences for schools and neighborhoods. J. Political Econ. 115:588–638
    [Google Scholar]
  25. Becker G 1964. Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special Reference to Education Chicago: Univ. Chicago Press
  26. Bettinger E 2011. Educational vouchers in international contexts. Handbook of the Economics of Education 4 E Hanushek, S Machin, L Woessmann551–72 Amsterdam: Elsevier
    [Google Scholar]
  27. Bettinger E, Kremer M, Kugler M, Medina C, Posso C, Saavedra JE 2017. Can educational voucher programs pay for themselves? Unpublished manuscript Harvard Univ. Cambridge, MA
  28. Bettinger E, Kremer M, Saavedra JE 2010. Are educational vouchers only redistributive. Econ. J. 120F204–28
    [Google Scholar]
  29. Beuermann DW, Jackson CK 2018. Do parents know best? The short and long-run effects of attending the schools that parents prefer NBER Work. Pap. 24920
  30. Black S 1999. Do better schools matter? Parental valuation of elementary education. Q. J. Econ. 114:577–99
    [Google Scholar]
  31. Black S, Devereux P 2011. Recent developments in intergenerational mobility. Handbook of Labor Economics 4 O Ashenfelter, D Card1487–541 Amsterdam: Elsevier
    [Google Scholar]
  32. Bohlmark A, Holmlund H, Lindahl M 2015. School choice and segregation: evidence from Sweden Work. Pap. 2015:8, Inst. Eval. Labour Market Educ. Policy, Uppsala, Swed.
  33. Bohlmark A, Lindahl M 2007. The impact of school choice on pupil achievement, segregation and costs: Swedish evidence Work. Pap. 2786, IZA, Bonn, Ger.
  34. Brasington D, Haurin D 2006. Educational outcomes and house values: a test of the value added approach. J. Reg. Sci. 46:245–68
    [Google Scholar]
  35. Bresnahan TF, Brynjolfsson E, Hitt LM 2002. Information technology, workplace organization, and the demand for skilled labor: firm-level evidence. Q. J. Econ. 117:339–76
    [Google Scholar]
  36. Browning M, Chiappori PA, Weiss Y 2014. Economics of the Family Cambridge, UK: Cambridge Univ. Press
  37. Bui SA, Craig SG, Imberman SA 2014. Is gifted education a bright idea? Assessing the impact of gifted and talented programs on students. Am. Econ. J. Econ. Policy 6:30–62
    [Google Scholar]
  38. Burgess S, Greaves E, Vignoles A, Wilson D 2015. What parents want: school preferences and school choice. Econ. J. 125:1262–89
    [Google Scholar]
  39. Caldwell S, Harmon N 2019. Outside options, bargaining, and wages: evidence from coworker networks Unpublished manuscript, Univ. Copenhagen
  40. Card D 2001. Estimating the return to schooling: progress on some persistent econometric problems. Econometrica 69:1127–60
    [Google Scholar]
  41. Card D, Cardoso AR, Heining J, Kline P 2018. Firms and labor market inequality: evidence and some theory. J. Lab. Econ. 36:84–111
    [Google Scholar]
  42. Card D, Devicienti F, Maida A 2014. Rent-sharing, holdup, and wages: evidence from matched panel data. Rev. Econ. Stud. 81:84–111
    [Google Scholar]
  43. Card D, Heining J, Kline P 2013. Workplace heterogeneity and the rise of West German wage inequality. Q. J. Econ. 128:967–1015
    [Google Scholar]
  44. Caroli E, van Reenen J 2001. Skill-biased organizational change? Evidence from a panel of British and French establishments. Q. J. Econ. 116:1449–92
    [Google Scholar]
  45. Chabrier J, Cohodes S, Oreopoulos P 2016. What can we learn from charter school lotteries. J. Econ. Perspect. 3057–84
    [Google Scholar]
  46. Chakrabarti R 2008. Can increasing private school participation and monetary loss in a voucher program affect public school performance? Evidence from Milwaukee. J. Public Econ. 92:1371–93
    [Google Scholar]
  47. Cheshire P, Sheppard S 2004. Capitalising the value of free schools: the impact of supply characteristics and uncertainty. Econ. J. 114:F397–424
    [Google Scholar]
  48. Chetty R, Friedman JN, Hilger N, Saez E, Schanzenbach DW, Yagan D 2011. How does your kindergarten classroom affect your earnings? Evidence from Project STAR. Q. J. Econ. 126:1593–660
    [Google Scholar]
  49. Chetty R, Friedman JN, Rockoff J 2014a. Measuring the impacts of teachers I: evaluating bias in teacher value-added estimates. Am. Econ. Rev. 104:2593–632
    [Google Scholar]
  50. Chetty R, Friedman JN, Rockoff J 2014b. Measuring the impacts of teachers II: teacher value-added and student outcomes in adulthood. Am. Econ. Rev. 104:2633–79
    [Google Scholar]
  51. Chetty R, Friedman JN, Rockoff J 2017a. Measuring the impacts of teachers: reply. Am. Econ. Rev. 107:1685–717
    [Google Scholar]
  52. Chetty R, Friedman JN, Saez E, Turner N, Yagan D 2017b. Mobility report cards: the role of colleges in intergenerational mobility Unpublished manuscript, Stanford Univ., Stanford, CA
  53. Chetty R, Hendren N, Kline P, Saez E 2014c. Where is the land of opportunity? The geography of intergenerational mobility in the United States NBER Work. Pap. 19843
  54. Clark D 2010. Selective schools and academic achievement. B.E. J. Econ. Anal. Policy 10:1935–1682
    [Google Scholar]
  55. Cohodes SR 2018. Charter schools and the achievement gap. The Future of Children, Winter. https://futureofchildren.princeton.edu/news/charter-schools-and-achievement-gap
    [Google Scholar]
  56. Dale SB, Krueger AB 2002. Estimating the payoff to attending a more selective college: an application of selection on observables and unobservables. Q. J. Econ. 117:1491–527
    [Google Scholar]
  57. Dale SB, Krueger AB 2014. Estimating the effects of college characteristics over the career using administrative earnings data. J. Hum. Resourc. 49:323–58
    [Google Scholar]
  58. Davidoff I, Leigh A 2008. How much do public schools really cost? Estimating the relationship between house prices and school quality. Econ. Record 84:193–206
    [Google Scholar]
  59. Davis DR, Dingel JI 2014. The comparative advantage of cities NBER Work. Pap. 20602
  60. Davis DR, Dingel JI 2019. A spatial knowledge economy. Am. Econ. Rev. 109:153–70
    [Google Scholar]
  61. de Ree J, Muralidharan K, Pradhan M, Rogers H 2018. Double for nothing? Experimental evidence on an unconditional teacher salary increase in Indonesia. Q. J. Econ. 133:993–1039
    [Google Scholar]
  62. Dobbie W, Fryer R 2014. The impact of attending a school with high-achieving peers: evidence from New York City exam schools. Am. Econ. J. Appl. Econ. 6:58–75
    [Google Scholar]
  63. Epple D, Romano R, Urquiola M 2017. School vouchers: a survey of the economics literature. J. Econ. Lit. 55:441–92
    [Google Scholar]
  64. Epple D, Romano R, Zimmer R 2016. Charter schools: a survey of research on their characteristics and effectiveness. Handbook of the Economics of Education 5 E Hanushek, S Machin, L Woessmann139–208 Amsterdam: Elsevier
    [Google Scholar]
  65. Epple D, Romano RE 1998. Competition between private and public schools, vouchers, and peer-group effects. Am. Econ. Rev. 88:33–62
    [Google Scholar]
  66. Fack G, Grenet J 2010. When do better schools raise housing prices? Evidence from Paris public and private schools. J. Public Econ. 94:59–77
    [Google Scholar]
  67. Farber HS, Gibbons R 1996. Learning and wage dynamics. Q. J. Econ. 111:1007–47
    [Google Scholar]
  68. Feigenberg B, Rivkin S, Yan R 2014. Illusory gains from Chile's targeted school voucher experiment NBER Work. Pap. 23178
  69. Figlio D, Lucas M 2004. What's in a grade? School report cards and house prices. Am. Econ. Rev. 94:591–604
    [Google Scholar]
  70. Friedman M 1955. The role of government in education. Economics and the Public Interest RA Solo124–44 New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers Univ. Press
    [Google Scholar]
  71. Gallego F, Hernando A 2009. School choice in Chile: looking at the demand side Unpublished manuscript, Pontif. Univ. Catol. Chile, Santiago
  72. Gibbons S, Machin S 2003. Valuing English primary schools. J. Urban Econ. 53:197–219
    [Google Scholar]
  73. Gibbons S, Machin S 2008. Valuing school quality, better transport and lower crime: evidence from house prices. Oxf. Rev. Econ. Policy 24:99–119
    [Google Scholar]
  74. Gilraine M, Petronijevic U, Singleton JD 2019. Horizontal differentiation and the policy effect of charter schools Unpublished manuscript, New York Univ.
  75. Granovetter MS 1973. The strength of weak ties. Am. J. Sociol. 78:1360–80
    [Google Scholar]
  76. Gundlach E, Woessman L, Gmelin J 2001. What parents want: school preferences and school choice. Econ. J. 471:C135–47
    [Google Scholar]
  77. Hanushek E 1981. Throwing money at schools. J. Policy Anal. Manag. 1:19–41
    [Google Scholar]
  78. Hanushek E 1997. The productivity collapse in schools. Developments in School Finance W Fowler183–95 Washington, DC: Natl. Cent. Educ. Stat.
    [Google Scholar]
  79. Hanushek EA, Kain JF, Rivkin SG, Branch GF 2007. Charter school quality and parental decision making with school choice. J. Public Econ. 91:823–48
    [Google Scholar]
  80. Hanushek EA, Woessmann L 2010. Education and economic growth. Economics of Education DJ Brewer, PJ McEwan60–67 Amsterdam: Elsevier
    [Google Scholar]
  81. Hastings J, Kane T, Staiger D 2009. Heterogeneous preferences and the efficacy of public school choice Unpublished manuscript, Brown Univ., Providence, RI
  82. Hastings J, Weinstein J 2008. Information, school choice, and academic achievement: evidence from two experiments. Q. J. Econ. 123:1373–414
    [Google Scholar]
  83. Hoekstra M 2009. The effect of attending the flagship state university on earnings: a discontinuity-based approach. Rev. Econ. Stat. 91:717–24
    [Google Scholar]
  84. Hoekstra M, Mouganie P, Wang Y 2018. Peer quality and the academic benefits to attending better schools. J. Labor Econ. 36:841–84
    [Google Scholar]
  85. Hoxby C 2000. Does competition among public schools benefit students and taxpayers. Am. Econ. Rev. 901209–38
    [Google Scholar]
  86. Hoxby C 2002. How school choice affects the achievement of public school students. Choice with Equity P Hill141–78 Stanford, CA: Hoover Press
    [Google Scholar]
  87. Hoxby C 2009. The changing selectivity of American colleges. J. Econ. Perspect. 23:95–118
    [Google Scholar]
  88. Hoxby C, Avery C 2012. The missing ‘one-offs’: the hidden supply of high-achieving, low income students NBER Work. Pap. 18586
  89. Hoxby C, Turner S 2013. Expanding college opportunities for high-achieving, low-income students Work. Pap. 12-014, Stanford Inst. Econ. Policy Res., Stanford, CA
  90. Hoxby CM 2003. School choice and school productivity: Could school choice be a tide that lifts all boats. The Economics of School Choice CM Hoxby287–41 Chicago: Univ. Chicago Press
    [Google Scholar]
  91. Hoxby CM 2016. The productivity of U.S. postsecondary institutions NBER Work. Pap. 13875
  92. Hsieh CT, Urquiola M 2003. When schools compete, how do they compete? An assessment of Chile's nationwide school voucher program NBER Work. Pap. 10008
  93. Hsieh CT, Urquiola M 2006. The effects of generalized school choice on achievement and stratification: evidence from Chile's school voucher program. J. Public Econ. 90:1477–503
    [Google Scholar]
  94. Imberman S, Lovenheim M 2016. Does the market value value-added? Evidence from housing prices after a public release of school and teacher value-added. J. Urban Econ. 91:104–21
    [Google Scholar]
  95. Jackson CK 2010. Do students benefit from attending better schools? Evidence from rule based student assignments in Trinidad and Tobago. Econ. J. 120:1399–429
    [Google Scholar]
  96. Jackson CK, Johnson RC, Persico C 2016. The effects of school spending on educational and economic outcomes: evidence from school finance reforms. Q. J. Econ. 131:157–218
    [Google Scholar]
  97. Kahn SR 2011. Privilege: The Making of an Adolescent Elite at St. Paul's School Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press
  98. Kaufmann KM, Messner M, Solis A 2013. Returns to elite higher education in the marriage market: evidence from Chile Unpublished manuscript, Bocconi Univ., Milan, Italy
  99. Kraft M 2019. Teacher effects on complex cognitive skills and socio-emotional competencies. J. Hum. Resourc. 54:1–36
    [Google Scholar]
  100. Krueger AB, Summers LH 1988. Efficiency wages and the inter-industry wage structure. Econometrica 56:259–94
    [Google Scholar]
  101. Lafortune J, Rothstein J, Schanzenbach D 2018. School finance reform and the distribution of student achievement. Am. Econ. J. Appl. Econ. 10:1–26
    [Google Scholar]
  102. Lemieux T 2006. The “Mincer equation” thirty years after Schooling, Experience, and Earnings. Jacob Mincer, A Pioneer of Modern Labor Economics S Grossbard127–45 Berlin: Springer
    [Google Scholar]
  103. Liptak A 2009. On the bench and off, the eminently quotable Justice Scalia. The New York TimesMay 11 https://www.nytimes.com/2009/05/12/us/12bar.html
    [Google Scholar]
  104. Lucas A, Mbiti I 2014. Effects of school quality on student achievement: discontinuity evidence from Kenya. Am. Econ. J. Appl. Econ. 6:234–63
    [Google Scholar]
  105. Machin S 2011. Houses and schools: valuation of school quality through the housing market. Labor Econ. 18:723–29
    [Google Scholar]
  106. MacLeod WB, Riehl E, Saavedra JE, Urquiola M 2017. The big sort: college reputation and labor market outcomes. Am. Econ. J. Appl. Econ. 9:223–61
    [Google Scholar]
  107. MacLeod WB, Urquiola M 2015. Reputation and school competition. Am. Econ. Rev. 105:3471–88
    [Google Scholar]
  108. McEwan P 2004. The potential impact of vouchers. Peabody J. Educ. 79:57–80
    [Google Scholar]
  109. McEwan P, Urquiola M, Vegas E 2008. School choice, stratification, and information on school performance. Economia 8:1–42
    [Google Scholar]
  110. McMillan P 2005. Competition, incentives, and public school productivity. J. Public Econ. 89:1131–54
    [Google Scholar]
  111. Mincer J 1974. Schooling, Experience and Earnings New York: Columbia Univ. Press
  112. Mizala A, Romaguera P, Urquiola M 2007. Socioeconomic status or noise? Tradeoffs in the generation of school quality information. J. Dev. Econ. 84:61–75
    [Google Scholar]
  113. Mizala A, Urquiola M 2013. Parental choice and school markets: the impact of information on school effectiveness. J. Dev. Econ. 103:313–35
    [Google Scholar]
  114. Moon TS 2018. Access to local amenity and housing prices Tech. Rep., Princeton Univ., Princeton, NJ
  115. Moretti E 2004. Workers’ education, spillovers and productivity: evidence from plant-level production functions. Am. Econ. Rev. 94:656–90
    [Google Scholar]
  116. Moretti E 2011. Local labor markets. Handbook of Labor Economics 4B D Card, O Ashenfelter1237–313 Amsterdam: Elsevier
    [Google Scholar]
  117. Muralidharan K, Sundararaman V 2015. The aggregate effect of school choice: evidence from a two-stage experiment in India. Q. J. Econ. 130:1011–66
    [Google Scholar]
  118. Navarro-Palau P 2017. Effects of differentiated school vouchers: evidence from a policy change and date of birth cutoffs. Econ. Educ. Rev. 58:86–107
    [Google Scholar]
  119. Neckerman K, Torche F 2007. Inequality: causes and consequences. Annu. Rev. Sociol. 33:263–83
    [Google Scholar]
  120. Neilson C 2017. Targeted vouchers, competition among schools, and the academic achievement of poor students Unpublished manuscript, Princeton Univ., Princeton, NJ
  121. Oreopoulos P, von Wachter T, Heisz A 2012. The short- and long-term career effects of graduating in a recession. Am. Econ. J. Appl. Econ. 4:1–29
    [Google Scholar]
  122. Park A, Shi X, Hsieh CT, An X 2008. Does school quality matter? Evidence from a natural experiment in rural China Unpublished manuscript, Univ. Chicago
  123. Pop-Eleches C, Urquiola M 2013. Going to a better school: effects and behavioral responses. Am. Econ. Rev. 103:1289–324
    [Google Scholar]
  124. Pritchett L 2009. The policy irrelevance of the economics of education: Is ‘normative as positive’ just useless, or is it worse. What Works in Development? Thinking Big and Thinking Small J Cohen, W Easterly130–64 Washington, DC: Brookings Inst. Press
    [Google Scholar]
  125. Riehl E 2018. Fairness in college admission exams: from test score gaps to earnings inequality Unpublished manuscript, Cornell Univ., Ithaca, NY
  126. Riehl E, Saavedra J, Urquiola M 2016. Learning and earning: college output, value added, and socioeconomic status Unpublished manuscript, Columbia Univ., New York
  127. Rivera LA 2015. Pedigree: How Elite Students Get Elite Jobs Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press
  128. Rockoff JE, Jacob BA, Kane TJ, Staiger DO 2011. Can you recognize an effective teacher when you recruit one. Educ. Finance Policy 643–74
    [Google Scholar]
  129. Rosen S 1981. The economics of superstars. Am. Econ. Rev. 71:845–58
    [Google Scholar]
  130. Rosenthal M 2006. Nicholas Miraculous: The Amazing Career of the Redoubtable Dr. Nicholas Murray Butler New York: Farrar Strauss Giroux
  131. Rothstein J 2006. Good principals or good peers: parental valuation of school characteristics, Tiebout equilibrium, and the incentive effects of competition among jurisdictions. Am. Econ. Rev. 96:1333–50
    [Google Scholar]
  132. Rothstein J 2007. Does competition among public schools benefit students and taxpayers? Comment. Am. Econ. Rev. 95:2026–37
    [Google Scholar]
  133. Rothstein J 2017. Measuring the impact of teachers: comment. Am. Econ. Rev. 107:1656–84
    [Google Scholar]
  134. Rouse CE, Barrow L 2009. School vouchers and student achievement: recent evidence and remaining questions. Annu. Rev. Econ. 1:17–42
    [Google Scholar]
  135. Saavedra J 2009. The learning and early labor market effects of college quality: a regression discontinuity analysis Unpublished manuscript, Harvard Univ., Cambridge, MA
  136. Tiebout C 1956. A pure theory of local expenditures. J. Political Econ. 64:416–24
    [Google Scholar]
  137. Urquiola M 2005. Does school choice lead to sorting? Evidence from Tiebout variation. Am. Econ. Rev. 95:1310–26
    [Google Scholar]
  138. Urquiola M 2016. Competition among schools: traditional public and private schools. Handbook of the Economics of Education 5 E Hanushek, S Machin, L Woessmann209–37 Amsterdam: Elsevier
    [Google Scholar]
  139. Valenzuela J, Bellei C, De Los Rios D 2013. Socioeconomic school segregation in a market-oriented educational system: the case of Chile. J. Educ. Policy 29:217–41
    [Google Scholar]
  140. Van Reenen J 1996. The creation and capture of rents: wages and innovation in a panel of U.K. companies. Q. J. Econ. 111:195–226
    [Google Scholar]
  141. von Wachter T, Bender S 2006. In the right place at the wrong time: the role of firms and luck in young workers’ careers. Am. Econ. Rev. 96:1679–705
    [Google Scholar]
  142. Walters CR 2018. The demand for effective charter schools. J. Political Econ. 126:2179–223
    [Google Scholar]
  143. Weinstein R 2017. Geography and employer recruiting Tech. Rep. 11224, IZA, Bonn, Ger.
  144. Zimmerman S 2016. Making the one percent: the role of elite universities and elite peers NBER Work. Pap. 22900
/content/journals/10.1146/annurev-economics-080218-030402
Loading
  • Article Type: Review Article
This is a required field
Please enter a valid email address
Approval was a Success
Invalid data
An Error Occurred
Approval was partially successful, following selected items could not be processed due to error