Skip to main content
Log in

Non-linear pattern of international capital flows

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Review of World Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In a two-country OLG model with interest rate wedges capturing financial frictions, international capital flows can follow a non-linear pattern, depicted as a U-shaped curve, by first decreasing and then increasing in growth. The turning point of the curve is determined by the world average growth rate and these interest rate wedges. The model developed in this paper can reconcile different theories (i.e, the implications of the neoclassical growth model, up-hill capital flows, and the allocation puzzle) on the pattern of international capital flows.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Alfaro, L., Kalemli-Ozcan, S., & Volosovych, V. (2014). Sovereigns, upstream capital flows, and global imbalances. Journal of the European Economic Association, 12(5), 1240–1284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aguiar, M., & Amador, M. (2011). Growth in the shadow of expropriation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126(2), 651–697.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benhima, K. (2013). A reappraisal of the allocation puzzle through the portfolio approach. Journal of International Economics, 89(2), 331–346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, B. S. (2005). The global saving glut and the US current account deficit. No. 77.

  • Boyd, J. H., & Smith, B. D. (1997). Capital market imperfections, international credit markets, and nonconvergence. Journal of Economic Theory, 73(2), 335–364.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caselli, F., & Feyrer, J. (2007). The marginal product of capital. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(2), 535–568.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coeurdacier, N., Guibaud, S., & Jin, K. (2015). Credit constraints and growth in a global economy. The American Economic Review, 105(9), 2838–2881.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caballero, R.J., Farhi, E., & Gourinchas, P.-O. (2008). An equilibrium model of “global imbalances” and low interest rates. American Economic Review, 98(1), 358–393.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gertler, M., & Rogoff, K. (1990). North–South lending and endogenous domestic capital market inefficiencies. Journal of Monetary Economics, 26(2), 245–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gourinchas, P.-O., & Jeanne, O. (2013). Capital flows to developing countries: The allocation puzzle. Review of Economic Studies, 80(4), 1484–1515.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gourinchas, P.-O., & Rey, H. (2014). External adjustment, global imbalances, valuation effects. Handbook of International Economics, 4, 585–645.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E. (1990). Why doesn’t capital flow from rich to poor countries? The American Economic Review, 80(2), 92–96.

    Google Scholar 

  • Matsuyama, K. (2004). Financial market globalization, symmetry-breaking, and endogenous inequality of nations. Econometrica, 72(3), 853–884.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld, M., & Rogoff, K. S. (1996). Foundations of international macroeconomics (Vol. 30). Cambridge, MA: MIT press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ohanian, L. E., Restrepo-Echavarria, P., & Wright, M. L. J. (2015). Bad investments and missed opportunities? Capital flows to Asia and Latin America, 1950–2007. Los Angeles: University of California Los Angeles.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prasad, E. S., Rajan, R. G., & Subramanian, A., (2007). Foreign capital and economic growth. No. w13619. National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Solow, R. M. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70(1), 65–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hung Ly-Dai.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

The author grateful for helpful comments from Cuong Le Van, Jean-Bernard Chatelain, Ha Huy Thai, Ngoc-Sang Pham, Nguyen Thi Bich Hanh, Nguyen Dinh Minh Anh, the editor, two anonymous reviewers, and participants in the economics seminars at the Paris School of Economics and Bielefeld Graduate School of Economics and Management. The author acknowledges financial support from the European Commission in the framework of the European Doctorate in Economics—Erasmus Mundus (EDEEM).

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (pdf 1376 KB)

Appendices

Appendix

1 Definition of equilibrium

Definition 1

The autarky temporal equilibrium.

Given the value determined in the last period \((S_{t-1})\), the exogenous variable \((A_t,N_t)\), and the expected interest rate with perfect foresight \((R^{l}_{t+1})\), the temporary equilibrium is a list of prices \((R^l_t, R^d_t, R_t,w_t)\), allocations \((c^y_t, c^o_t, s_t, I_t)\), and aggregate variables \((K_t, S_t, L_t, Y_t)\) such that:

  1. 1.

    Profit is maximized and utility is maximized subjected to the budget constraint.

  2. 2.

    The market clearing conditions are satisfied:

    1. (a)

      Labor market: \(L_t = N_t\)

    2. (b)

      Capital market: \(K_{t} = S_{t-1} = N_{t-1} s_{t-1}\)

    3. (c)

      Goods market: \(N_t c^y_t + N_t s_t + N_{t-1} c^o_t = Y_t\)

Definition 2

The autarky inter-temporal equilibrium.

Given an initial lending interest rate \((R^l_{t=0})\), an inter-temporal equilibrium with perfect foresight is a sequence of temporary equilibria that satisfies for all \((t>0)\) the conditions that:

$$\begin{aligned} k(R^l_{t+1},\gamma )=\; & {} s(R^l_t, R^l_{t+1}, \tau , \gamma ) \\ \Leftrightarrow \left(\dfrac{\alpha (1-\gamma )}{R^l_{t+1}}\right)^{1/(1-\alpha )}= & {} \dfrac{(1-\alpha ){(\alpha (1-\gamma ))}^{\alpha /(1-\alpha )}\beta (1-\tau )}{(1+\beta (1-\tau )){(R^l_t)}^{\alpha /(1-\alpha )}} \dfrac{1}{(1+g^A_{t+1})(1+g^N_{t+1})}- \dfrac{\gamma \alpha [\alpha (1-\gamma )]^{\alpha /(1-\alpha )}}{(1+\beta (1-\tau ))(R^l_{t+1})^{1/(1-\alpha )}} \end{aligned}$$

Definition 3

The integration temporal equilibrium.

For country (j) in a two-country economy, given the value determined in the last period \((S^j_{t-1})\), the exogenous variable \((A^j_t,N^j_t)\), and the expected world interest rate with perfect foresight \((R^{l,w}_{t+1})\), the temporary equilibrium is a list of prices \((R^{l,w}_t, R^{d,j}_t, R^j_t,w^j_t)\), allocations \((c^{y,j}_t, c^{o,j}_t, s^j_t, I^j_t)\), and aggregate variables \((K^j_t, S^j_t, L^j_t, Y^j_t)\) in each country j such that:

  1. 1.

    Profit is maximized and utility is maximized subjected to the budget constraint.

  2. 2.

    The market clearing conditions are satisfied:

    1. (a)

      Labor market: \(L^{D,j}_t = N^j_t\)

    2. (b)

      World capital market: \(\Sigma _j K^j_{t} = \Sigma _j S^j_{t-1} \equiv \Sigma _j N^j_{t-1} s^j_{t-1}\)

    3. (c)

      World goods market: \(\Sigma _j (N^j_t c^{y,j}_t + N^j_t s^j_t + N^j_{t-1} c^{o,j}_t ) = \Sigma _j Y^j_t\)

Definition 4

The integration inter-temporal equilibrium.

For country j in a two-country economy, given an initial world lending interest rate \((R^{l,w}_{t=0})\), an inter-temporal equilibrium with perfect foresight is a sequence of temporary equilibria that satisfies for all \(t>0\) the conditions:

$$\begin{aligned} \Sigma _j \dfrac{A^j_{t} N^j_{t}}{\Sigma _jA^j_{t} N^j_{t}} k(R^{l,w}_{t+1},\gamma ^j)=\; & {} \Sigma _j \dfrac{A^j_{t} N^j_{t}}{\Sigma _jA^j_{t} N^j_{t}} s(R^{l,w}_t, R^{l,w}_{t+1}, \tau ^j, \gamma ^j) \end{aligned}$$

where \(k(R^{l,w}_{t+1},\gamma ^j)\equiv \dfrac{K^j_{t+1}}{A^j_{t} N^j_{t}};\; s(R^{l,w}_t, R^{l,w}_{t+1}, \tau ^j, \gamma ^j)\equiv \dfrac{S^j_t}{A^j_{t}N^j_{t}}\).

2 Proofs

Theorem 2.2.1

Proof

We define the function \(\Delta (R^l_{t+1}, R^l_t)\) as follows:

$$\begin{aligned}&\Delta (R^l_{t+1}, R^l_t) \equiv k(R^l_{t+1},\gamma ) - s(R^l_{t+1},R^l_t,\tau ,\gamma ) \\&\quad= \left[ (\alpha (1-\gamma ))^{1/(1-\alpha )}+\dfrac{\gamma \alpha [\alpha (1-\gamma )]^{\alpha /(1-\alpha )}}{1+\beta (1-\tau )}\right] \dfrac{(1+g^A_{t+1})(1+g^N_{t+1})}{(R^l_{t+1})^{1/(1-\alpha )}}- \dfrac{(1-\alpha ){(\alpha (1-\gamma ))}^{\alpha /(1-\alpha )}\beta (1-\tau )}{1+\beta (1-\tau )}\dfrac{1}{{(R^l_t)}^{\alpha /(1-\alpha )}} \end{aligned}$$
  1. 1.

    Existence of steady state

    $$\begin{aligned} \lim _{R^l_{t+1} \rightarrow 0} \Delta (R^l_{t+1}, R^l_t) > 0 \hbox { and} \lim _{R^l_{t+1} \rightarrow \infty } \Delta (R^l_{t+1}, R^l_t) < 0 \end{aligned}$$
  2. 2.

    Uniqueness and global stability.

Since \(\dfrac{\partial \Delta (R^l_{t+1}, R^l_t)}{\partial R^l_{t+1}} \ne 0\), \(R^l_{t+1}\) is an implicit function of \(R^l_t\), denoted by: \(R^l_{t+1} = h(R^l_t)\). By the implicit function theorem, \(\dfrac{\partial R^l_{t+1}}{\partial R^l_t}>0\), since:

$$\begin{aligned}&\dfrac{\partial \Delta }{\partial R^l_{t+1}} = - \left[ (\alpha (1-\gamma ))^{1/(1-\alpha )}+\dfrac{\gamma \alpha [\alpha (1-\gamma )]^{\alpha /(1-\alpha )}}{1+\beta (1-\tau )}\right] \dfrac{(1+g^A_{t+1})(1+g^N_{t+1})}{(1-\alpha )(R^l_{t+1})^{(2-\alpha )/(1-\alpha )}}<0\\&\dfrac{\partial \Delta }{\partial R^l_{t}} = \dfrac{\alpha {(\alpha (1-\gamma ))}^{\alpha /(1-\alpha )}\beta (1-\tau )}{1+\beta (1-\tau )}\dfrac{1}{{(R^l_t)}^{1/(1-\alpha )}}>0 \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, \(h(R^l_t)\) is a monotonically increasing function and converges to a positive value, if any. By l’Hôpital’s rule, the graph of \(h(R^l_t)\) would be below the 45 degree line for a large enough value of \(R^l_t\).

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{R^l_t \rightarrow \infty } \dfrac{R^l_{t+1}}{R^l_t} = 0 <1 \end{aligned}$$

In sum, \(R^l_{t+1} = h(R^l_t)\) is both a monotonically increasing and concave function. Then, it would converge to a finite positive value \(0<R^l<\infty\). The comparative statics are easy to derive since we have a closed-form solution for the interest rate for \(\sigma =1\). \(\square\)

Theorem 2.2.2

Proof

For country j in a two-country economy, we define the function \(\Delta (R^{l,w}_{t+1}, R^{l,w}_t)\) as follows:

$$\begin{aligned}&\Delta (R^{l,w}_{t+1}, R^{l,w}_t) \equiv \Sigma _j \dfrac{A^j_{t} N^j_{t}}{\Sigma _jA^j_{t} N^j_{t}} k(R^{l,w}_{t+1},\gamma ^j) - \Sigma _j \dfrac{A^j_{t} N^j_{t}}{\Sigma _jA^j_{t} N^j_{t}} s(R^{l,w}_t, R^{l,w}_{t+1}, \tau ^j, \gamma ^j) \\&=\left( \dfrac{1}{R^{l,w}_{t+1}}\right) ^{1/(1-\alpha )} \Sigma _j \dfrac{A^j_{t} N^j_{t}}{\Sigma _jA^j_{t} N^j_{t}} \left[ (\alpha (1-\gamma ^j))^{1/(1-\alpha )}+\dfrac{\gamma ^j\alpha [\alpha (1-\gamma ^j)]^{\alpha /(1-\alpha )}}{1+\beta (1-\tau ^j)}\right] (1+g^{A,j}_{t+1}) (1+g^{N,j}_{t+1}) \\&\quad - \left( \dfrac{1}{R^{l,w}_t}\right) ^{\alpha /(1-\alpha )} \Sigma _j \dfrac{A^j_{t} N^j_{t}}{\Sigma _jA^j_{t} N^j_{t}} \dfrac{(1-\alpha ){(\alpha (1-\gamma ))}^{\alpha /(1-\alpha )}\beta (1-\tau ^j)}{(1+\beta (1-\tau ^j))} \end{aligned}$$
  1. 1.

    Existence of steady state

    $$\begin{aligned} \lim _{R^{l,w}_{t+1} \rightarrow 0} \Delta (R^{l,w}_{t+1}, R^{l,w}_t) > 0 \hbox { and} \lim _{R^{l,w}_{t+1} \rightarrow \infty } \Delta (R^{l,w}_{t+1}, R^{l,w}_t) < 0 \end{aligned}$$
  2. 2.

    Uniqueness and global stability

Since \(\dfrac{\partial \Delta (R^{l,w}_{t+1}, R^{l,w}_t)}{\partial R^{l,w}_{t+1}} \ne 0\), then \(R^{l,w}_{t+1}\) is a function of \(R^{l,w}_t: R^{l,w}_{t+1} \equiv h(R^{l,w}_t)\).

By the implicit function theorem, \(\dfrac{\partial \Delta }{\partial R^{l,w}_{t+1}} < 0\) and \(\dfrac{\partial \Delta }{\partial R^{l,w}_{t}} > 0\). Then, \(\dfrac{\partial R^{l,w}_{t+1}}{\partial R^{l,w}_t}>0\). Therefore, \(h(R^{l,w}_t)\) is a monotonically increasing function, and it would converge to a positive value, if any.

Moreover, by l’Hôpital’s rule,

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{R^{l,w}_t \rightarrow \infty } \dfrac{R^{l,w}_{t+1}}{R^{l,w}_t} = 0 <1 \end{aligned}$$

In sum, \(R^{l,w}_{t+1} = h(R^{l,w}_t)\) is both a monotonically increasing and concave function since its graph would be below the 45 degree line for a large enough value of \(R^{l,w}_t\). Then, it would converge to a finite positive value \(0<R^{l,w}<\infty\).

For the case of a symmetric growth rate across countries, \(\lambda ^j_t\equiv \dfrac{Y^j_t}{Y^w_t}, \theta ^j_t\equiv \dfrac{\lambda ^j_t \vartheta ^j}{\bar{\vartheta }}\),

$$\begin{aligned} R^{l,w}_t=\; & {} \dfrac{\alpha }{(1-\alpha )} \dfrac{Y^w_t}{Y^w_{t-1}} \left( \dfrac{\Sigma _j \lambda ^j_t \left[ \mu (\gamma ^j,\tau ^j)+1-\gamma ^j\right] }{\bar{\vartheta }}\right) = \dfrac{\alpha }{(1-\alpha )} \dfrac{Y^w_t}{Y^w_{t-1}} \Sigma _j \lambda ^j_t \dfrac{\vartheta ^j}{\bar{\vartheta }} \left( \dfrac{\left[ \mu (\gamma ^j,\tau ^j)+1-\gamma ^j\right] }{\vartheta ^j}\right) \\=\; & {} \dfrac{\alpha }{(1-\alpha )} \dfrac{Y^w_t}{Y^w_{t-1}} \Sigma _j \theta ^j_t \left( \dfrac{\left[ \mu (\gamma ^j,\tau ^j)+1-\gamma ^j\right] }{\vartheta ^j}\right) =\Sigma _j \theta ^j_t R^{l,j}_t \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, \(min_j R^{l,j}_t< R^{l,w}_t < max_j R^{l,j}_t\). \(\square\)

Appendix 3: CRRA utility

We show that, with a general utility function, the main mechanism whereby the equilibrium interest rate is increasing in the saving wedge still holds. Therefore, the use of log-utility in the main text is valid.

In particular, we employ the standard isoelastic preferences \(u(c) = (c^{1-1/\sigma } - 1)/(1-1/\sigma )\), where \(\sigma\) is the intertemporal elasticity of substitution coefficient. The Euler equation yields the saving function for the young agent.

$$\begin{aligned} \dfrac{u'(c^y_t)}{u'(c^o_{t+1})} = \beta (1-\tau ) R^l_{t+1} \Rightarrow s_t = \dfrac{w_t - (\beta (1-\tau ) R^l_{t+1})^{-\sigma } z_{t+1}}{1+\beta ^{-\sigma } ((1-\tau ) R^l_{t+1})^{(1-\sigma )}} \end{aligned}$$
(21)

Using the income transfer (6), the shares of output allocated to labor income \((w_t N_t = (1-\alpha )Y_t)\) and capital income \((R_{t+1} I_{t+1} =R_{t+1} K_{t+1} = \alpha Y_{t+1})\), we obtain the total savings in equilibrium.

$$\begin{aligned} S_t = N_t s_t=\dfrac{(1-\alpha ) Y_{t} - [\beta (1-\tau ) R^l_{t+1}]^{-\sigma } \gamma \alpha Y_{t+1}}{1+[\beta (1-\tau )]^{-\sigma } (R^l_{t+1})^{(1-\sigma )}} \end{aligned}$$

With an income transfer by the government, the saving wedge enters the saving-output ratio \((S_t/Y_t)\) with the power \((-\sigma )\). Therefore, given the output growth rate \((Y_{t+1}/Y_t)\), the saving rate is always decreasing in the level of the saving wedge. As a result, a country with a smaller saving wedge would have a higher saving rate. Since the saving-output ratio is decreasing in the saving wedge for all values of the inter-temporal elasticity of substitution coefficient while the investment-output ratio is independent of the inter-temporal elasticity of substitution coefficient, we can focus on the case of log utility \((\sigma =1)\) without losing generality.

The positive impact of the saving wedge on the lending interest rate relies on the modeling of capital taxation. In the set-up where the income taxation is a transfer to the households, a larger saving wedge reduces savings, then raises the lending rate, even in the case of a more general isoelastic utility function. Indeed, by Eq. (21) in partial equilibrium, the wedge affects the deposit interest rate and, in turn, saving through the substitution and income effects. A larger wedge decreases the deposit rate, which, in turn, reduces the saving by the substitution effect but raises the saving by the income effect. Therefore, the role of the wedge in saving depends on the value of the inter-temporal substitution coefficient \((\sigma )\). In general equilibrium with the taxation income being transferred to households, the income effect disappears. Then, only the substitution effect works: a larger wedge curtails saving and raises the lending rate, given the investment demand.

However, when the taxation income is used to finance public expenditure, the relationship between saving and taxation depends on the value of \((\sigma )\). In the online Appendix, we show that with public expenditure and for \(0<\sigma <1\), the income effect dominates the substitution effect. In that case, the lending rate is decreasing in the saving wedge because a larger saving wedge raises the supply of savings, which reduces the autarky interest rate, given the investment demand.

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ly-Dai, H. Non-linear pattern of international capital flows. Rev World Econ 155, 575–600 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-019-00349-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-019-00349-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation