Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Learning-by-doing and business cycles in emerging economies

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Review of World Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines whether learning-by-doing plays an important role in emerging economies. A business cycle model with learning-by-doing is presented and estimated using the data of emerging and developed economies. Its performance is considered from the viewpoint of predictive performance and the business cycle moments focused on in recent studies, namely, high volatility of consumption relative to that of output, and highly countercyclical net exports. The model with learning-by-doing outperforms the trend productivity shocks proposed by Aguiar and Gopinath (J Polit Econ 115(1):69–102, 2007) in predictive performance and it can also replicate the key business cycle moments. This is made possible through enhancing the persistence of productivity shocks and affecting the household’s expectation of permanent income. Further, the model is consistent with the observed relationships between the business cycle moments and growth rates. These results suggest the essential role of learning-by-doing in emerging economies and imply a possible reason for the difference in business cycles in emerging and developed economies.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Hsieh’s (1999, 2002) studies are examples of growth accounting studies that examine the importance of productivity growth in emerging economies, in contrast to Young (1995) or Fernald and Neiman (2011).

  2. I use Uribe and Schmitt-Grohé’s (2017) quarterly data for the period 1980:Q1 to 2012:Q4. I retrieved their series for aggregate output, consumption, investment, exports, and imports. I focus on the same 11 emerging economies and 17 developed economies that Uribe and Schmitt-Grohé (2015) chose in examining the business cycle facts. Their sample of emerging economies includes Argentina, Israel, Korea, Mexico, New Zealand, Peru, Portugal, South Africa, Spain, Turkey, and Uruguay. The sample of developed economies includes Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Hong Kong, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the United States. Variables y and c are real output and consumption per capita, respectively, which are deseasonalized, logged, and Hodrick–Presscott (HP) filtered with a smoothing parameter of 1600. The mean quarterly growth rates of output for each country are calculated as the least squared mean of quarterly growth rate of deseasonalized output, following Canjels and Watson (1997).

  3. Following Aguiar and Gopinath (2007), the variable is normalized by trend productivity through period \(t-1\). The choice of normalization does not affect the solution to the model.

  4. The decrease in c/y does not necessarily make \(nx \approx 1-c/y-i/y\) procyclical, since the investment–output ratio i/y may increase in response to a positive productivity shock.

References

  • Aguiar, M., & Gopinath, G. (2007). Emerging market business cycles: The cycle is the trend. Journal of Political Economy, 115(1), 69–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aizenman, J., & Lee, J. (2010). Real exchange rate, mercantilism and the learning by doing externality. Pacific Economic Review, 15(3), 324–335.

    Google Scholar 

  • Akinci, Ö., & Charhrour, R. (2018). Good news is bad news: Leverage cycles and sudden stops. Journal of International Economics, 114, 362–375.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alberola, E., & Benigno, G. (2017). Revisiting the commodity curse: A financial perspective. Journal of International Economics, 108, S87–S106.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1962). The economic implications of learning by doing. Review of Economic Studies, 29(3), 155–173.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bahk, B.-H., & Gort, M. (1993). Decomposing learning by doing in new plants. Journal of Political Economy, 101(4), 561–583.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bean, C. (1990). Endogenous growth and the pro-cyclical behavior of productivity. European Economic Review, 34, 355–363.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benigno, G., & Fornaro, L. (2012). Reserve accumulation, growth and financial crises (CEP Discussion Paper No. 1161). Centre for Economic Performance.

  • Benigno, G., & Fornaro, L. (2014). The financial resource curse. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 116(1), 58–86.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bianchi, J. (2011). Overborrowing and systemic externalities in the business cycle. American Economic Review, 101(7), 3400–3426.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boz, E., Daude, C., & Durdu, C. B. (2011). Emerging market business cycles: Learning about the trend. Journal of Monetary Economics, 58, 616–631.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, J. Y., & Deaton, A. (1989). Why is consumption so smooth? Review of Economic Studies, 56, 357–373.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, R., & Fernández, A. (2013). On the sources of aggregate fluctuations in emerging economies. International Economic Review, 54(4), 1265–1293.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, Y., Gomes, J. F., & Schorfheide, F. (2002). Learning-by-doing as a propagation mechanism. American Economic Review, 92(5), 1498–1520.

    Google Scholar 

  • Canjels, E., & Watson, M. (1997). Estimating deterministic trends in the presence of serially correlated errors. Review of Economics and Statistics, 79(2), 184–200.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooper, R., & Johri, A. (2002). Learning-by-doing and aggregate fluctuations. Journal of Monetary Economics, 49, 1539–1566.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, D. S. (1987). The relationship between firm growth, size, and age: Estimates for 100 manufacturing industries. Journal of Industrial Economics, 35(4), 567–581.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fernald, J., & Neiman, B. (2011). Growth accounting with misallocation: Or, doing less with more in Singapore. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 3, 29–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fernández, A., & Gulan, A. (2015). Interest rates, leverage, and business cycles in emerging economies: The role of financial frictions. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 7(3), 153–188.

    Google Scholar 

  • García-Cicco, J., Pancrazi, R., & Uribe, M. (2010). Real business cycles in emerging countries? American Economic Review, 100(5), 2510–2531.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geweke, J. (1999). Using simulation methods for Bayesian econometric models: Inference, development and communication. Econometric Reviews, 18(1), 1–126.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hsieh, C.-T. (1999). Productivity growth and factor prices in East Asia. American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, 89(2), 133–138.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hsieh, C.-T. (2002). What explains the industrial revolution in East Asia? Evidence from the factor markets. American Economic Review, 92(3), 502–526.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ikeda, A. (2017). Trade balance volatility and consumption structures in small open economies. Economics Letters, 156, 114–117.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jeanne, O., & Korinek, A. (2010). Excessive volatility in capital flows: A Pigouvian taxation approach. American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, 100, 403–407.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korinek, A., & Servén, L. (2016). Undervaluation through foreign reserve accumulation: Static losses, dynamic gains. Journal of International Money and Finance, 64, 104–136.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E. (1993). Making a miracle. Econometrica, 61(2), 251–272.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, P., & Rogers, C. A. (2000). Long-term growth and short-term economic instability. European Economic Review, 44, 359–381.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mendoza, E. G. (1991). Real business cycles in a small open economy. American Economic Review, 81(4), 797–818.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mendoza, E. G. (2010). Sudden stops, financial crises, and leverage. American Economic Review, 100(5), 1941–1966.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neumeyer, P. A., & Perri, F. (2005). Business cycles in emerging economies: The role of interest rates. Journal of Monetary Economics, 52(2), 345–380.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prescott, E. C., & Visscher, M. (1980). Organization capital. Journal of Political Economy, 88(3), 446–461.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramey, G., & Ramey, V. A. (1995). Cross-country evidence on the link between volatility and growth. American Economic Review, 85(5), 1138–1151.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrick, D. (2008). The real exchange rate and economic growth: Theory and evidence. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall, 2008, 365–412.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. (1986). Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy, 94(5), 1002–1037.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saint-Paul, G. (1993). Productivity growth and the structure of the business cycle. European Economic Review, 37, 861–890.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmitt-Grohé, S., & Uribe, M. (2003). Closing small open economy models. Journal of International Economics, 61, 163–185.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smets, F., & Wouters, R. (2007). Shocks and frictions in US business cycles: A Bayesian DSGE approach. American Economic Review, 97(3), 586–606.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsuruga, T. (2007). The hump-shaped behavior of inflation and a dynamic externality. European Economic Review, 51, 1107–1125.

    Google Scholar 

  • Uribe, M., & Schmitt-Grohé, S. (2015). Online appendix to ‘Business-cycle facts around the world’. Retrieved February 24, 2019 from http://www.columbia.edu/~mu2166/book/empirics/empirics_online_appendix.pdf.

  • Uribe, M., & Schmitt-Grohé, S. (2017). Open Economy Macroeconomics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, A. (1993). Invention and bounded learning by doing. Journal of Political Economy, 101(3), 443–472.

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, A. (1995). The tyranny of numbers: Confronting the statistical realities of the East Asian growth experience. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3), 641–680.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I am grateful to Takayuki Tsuruga, Akihisa Shibata, Hiroshi Osano, Saroj Bhattarai, Olivier Coibion, Andrea Civelli, Jason Bergtold, Kenya Takaku, Dongya Koh, Hiroki Toyoda, Ayumu Tanaka, and Takehiro Kiguchi for their helpful comments. This work was supported by JSPS KAKENHI (Grant Number JP16J09356).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Akihiko Ikeda.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ikeda, A. Learning-by-doing and business cycles in emerging economies. Rev World Econ 156, 611–631 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-020-00373-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-020-00373-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation