Skip to main content
Log in

Evaluating horizontal mergers in the presence of price promotions

  • Published:
Quantitative Marketing and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, I investigate the impact of a horizontal merger between firms that use price promotions. I find that after the merger, the merged firms increase their prices, but coordinate the promotions by never discounting their products simultaneously. The non-merged firm responds with a more aggressive pricing strategy, offering deeper and more frequent discounts. The effects of a merger on the firms’ profits and the consumer surplus are very small relative to the case with no promotions. These conclusions are not affected by the size of the change in market concentration or by the degree of substitutability between the merging products. Thus, the use of price promotions by the merging firms can be viewed as a mitigating factor by the antitrust authorities.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In order to isolate the competitive implications of a merger, I assume it produces no efficiency gains.

  2. This reaction of a firm to a decrease in the number of rivals competing for the switchers is similar to the effect of a decrease in the number of firms in pricing models with mixed strategy equilibria (Rosenthal 1980; Stahl 1989). Since these models do not consider price coordination, the prices of all firms go down as the number of firms decreases, whereas in my model, the merged firms increase their prices.

  3. The findings for other non-merged firms were mixed. For Kellogg’s, prices of four brands went down while prices of five brands went up. All three Ralston brands increased their prices, and both Quaker brands decreased theirs.

  4. To prevent firms from earning infinite profits from their loyals, it is standard in the theoretical literature to set an exogenous reservation price for this segment. The price of an outside option serves this role in my model. To allow for different strength of preferences for their preferred brand, I introduce heterogeneity among the loyals.

  5. If there are no loyal consumers, i.e., α = 0, then the equilibrium is always in pure strategies and price promotions are not offered. In that case, all profits increase and the consumer surplus goes down after a merger (Werden and Froeb 1994).

  6. This is in contrast to the atomless mixed strategies in Varian (1980) and subsequent papers that work with discontinuous demands.

  7. The Matlab programs used to compute equilibria in this paper are available at https://sites.google.com/view/mergersandpromotions/home

  8. The robustness checked were performed for the values of α between 0.05 and 0.2, the values of μl between 0.01 and 0.5, and the values of p0 between 0.5 and 1.5. Parameter δi was varied in the first extension. Qualitative findings of the paper were not affected.

  9. Throughout the paper, I use the term “consumer heterogeneity” to refer to μ – the level of heterogeneity of the switching cohort.

  10. For example, when μ = 0.06, the firms use high price p3 = 0.73 charged with probability 0.14, shallow promotion p2 = 0.54 charged with probability 0.17, and deep promotion p1 = 0.17 charged with probability 0.69.

  11. The size of each bubble is proportional to the probability with which a corresponding price or a price pair is charged.

  12. With a small probability, the merged firms charge the high price for both products.

  13. The kinks and changes in monotonicity in this and the following figures happen when there is a change in the equilibrium structure due to firms adding more prices to the support of their price distributions.

  14. The expected consumer surplus is computed by taking a weighted average of the values of consumer surplus at all possible outcomes of the mixed strategies. For any price combination, the consumer surplus of the switchers is \( {CS}_s=\mu \ln \left({\sum}_{j=0}^3{e}^{U_{sj}/\mu}\right) \) while the consumer surplus of the segment loyal to product i is \( {CS}_{li}={\mu}_l\ln \left({\sum}_{j\in \left\{0;i\right\}}{e}^{U_{lj}/{\mu}_l}\right) \) (Small and Rosen 1981). The total consumer surplus is \( {CS}_s+{\sum}_{i=1}^3{CS}_{li} \).

  15. Formally, \( {CS}_s=\mu \ln \left({\sum}_{j=0}^3{e}^{U_{sj}/\mu}\right) \). Since ln is a concave function, an increase in CSs from product j going on sale (and corresponding increase in Usj) is larger when there are fewer other products on sale.

  16. Similar to the results in the previous section, since these two firms are symmetric, if in the equilibrium, they use price pair (pi, pj) with some probability, a mixed strategy that splits this probability in any way between (pi, pj) and (pj, pi) is also an equilibrium strategy.

  17. More flexible substitution patterns between differentiated products are estimated in the empirical literature using random coefficients models (Berry et al. 1995; Nevo 2000).

  18. To facilitate comparison between the strategies after two different mergers, in the symmetric case of the merger between firms 1 and 2, if the firms use price pair (pM1, pM2) with a certain probability, I split this probability equally between (pM1, pM2) and (pM2, pM1).

  19. When μ1 ≥ 0.136, firm 1 benefits more from the merger of firms 2 and 3. This is consistent with existing research that shows that a non-merged firm benefits more from a merger than the merged firms.

References

  • Ashenfelter, O., & Hosken, D. (2010). The effect of mergers on consumer prices: Evidence from five mergers on the enforcement margin. The Journal of Law and Economics, 53(3), 417–466.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berry, S., Levinsohn, J., & Pakes, A. (1995). Automobile Prices in Market Equilibrium. Econometrica, 63(4), 841–890.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brekke, K. R., L. Siciliani, O. R. Straume (2014). "Horizontal mergers and product quality," Norwegian School of Economics Working Paper.

  • Brito, D. (2003). Preemptive mergers under spatial competition. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 21(10), 1601–1622.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deneckere, R., & Davidson, C. (1985). Incentives to form coalitions with Bertrand competition. RAND Journal of Economics, 16(4), 473–486.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2004). Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers under the council regulation on the control of concentrations between undertakings. http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52004XC0205(02)&from=EN. Accessed 13 June 2019

  • Federgruen, A. and M. Pierson (2011) "The impact of horizontal mergers and acquisitions in Price competition models," HBS Working Paper 12–031.

  • Gandhi, A., Froeb, L., Tschantz, S., & Werden, G. J. (2008). Post-merger product repositioning. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 56(1), 49–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy, D. T., & Reitzes, J. D. (1992). Anticompetitive effects of mergers with localized competition. Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 8(2), 427–440.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lommerud, K. E., & Sørgard, L. (1997). Merger and product range rivalry. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 16(1), 21–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michel, C. (2016). "Identification and estimation of intra-firm and industry competition via ownership change," working paper, Universitat Pompeu Fabra.

  • Narasimhan, C. (1988). Competitive promotional strategies. Journal of Business, 61(4), 427–449.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nevo, A. (2000). Mergers with differentiated products: The case of the ready-to-eat cereal industry. RAND Journal of Economics, 31(3), 395–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Posada, P., & Straume, O. R. (2004). Merger, partial collusion and relocation. Journal of Economics, 83(3), 243–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenthal, R. W. (1980). A model in which an increase in the number of sellers leads to a higher Price. Econometrica, 48(6), 1575–1579.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sinitsyn, M. (2008a). Characterization of the support of the mixed strategy Price equilibria in oligopolies with heterogeneous consumers. Economics Letters, 99(2), 242–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sinitsyn, M. (2008b). Technical note-Price promotions in asymmetric duopolies with heterogeneous consumers. Management Science, 54(12), 2081–2087.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sinitsyn, M. (2009). Price dispersion in duopolies with heterogeneous consumers. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 27(2), 197–205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sinitsyn, M. (2012). Coordination of Price promotions in complementary categories. Management Science, 58(11), 2076–2094.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sinitsyn, M. (2016). Managing Price promotions within a product line. Marketing Science, 35(2), 304–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Small, K. A., & Rosen, H. S. (1981). Applied welfare economics with discrete choice models. Econometrica, 49(1), 105–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stahl, D. O. (1989). Oligopolistic pricing with sequential consumer search. American Economic Review, 79(4), 700–712.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tenn, S., Froeb, L., & Tschantz, S. (2010). Mergers when firms compete by choosing both Price and promotion. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 28(6), 695–707.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Department of Justice (DOJ) and the Federal Trade Commission (2010). Horizontal Merger Guidelines. http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/guidelines/hmg-2010.pdf.

  • Varian, H. R. (1980). A model of sales. American Economic Review, 70(4), 651–659.

    Google Scholar 

  • Werden, G. J., & Froeb, L. M. (1994). The effects of mergers in differentiated products industries: Logit demand and merger policy. Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 10(2), 407–426.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whinston, M. D. (2007). "Antitrust policy toward horizontal mergers," M. Armstrong, R. Porter, eds. Handbook of Industrial Organization, Vol. 3, Ch. 36, North Holland, 2369–2440.

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author thanks the co-editor Thomas Otter and two anonymous reviewers for their guidance in improving the paper. The author also benefited from the helpful comments of Ted Brandewie, Ryan Kasprzak, and Joel Sobel.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Maxim Sinitsyn.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Sinitsyn, M. Evaluating horizontal mergers in the presence of price promotions. Quant Mark Econ 18, 39–60 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-019-09213-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-019-09213-7

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation