Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Horizontal mergers and innovation in concentrated industries

  • Published:
Quantitative Marketing and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

It is an open question in antitrust economics whether allowing dominant firms to acquire smaller rivals is ultimately helpful or harmful to the long run rate of innovation and therefore long-term consumer welfare. I develop a framework to study this question in a dynamic oligopoly model where firms endogenously engage in investment, entry, exit and mergers. Firms produce vertically differentiated goods, compete by innovating on product quality, and can acquire rival firms to gain market power. In a benchmark model, mergers are modeled to be exclusively harmful to consumers in the short run by reducing competition and increasing prices. Despite this, under standard industry settings it is possible to show that the prospect of a buyout creates a powerful incentive for firms to preemptively enter the industry and invest to make themselves an attractive merger partner. The result is significantly higher rate of innovation with mergers than without and significantly higher long-run consumer welfare as well. Further results explore the circumstances under which this result is likely to hold. In order for the long run increase in innovation to outweigh the short run harm to consumers caused by mergers, entry costs must be low, entrants and incumbents must both have the ability to innovate rapidly, and the degree of horizontal product differentiation must be low. Alternatively, when dominant firms can directly incorporate the acquired firm’s innovation into their own product, mergers will typically benefit consumers in both the short run and long run.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Katz and Shelanski (2006) and Gilbert (2006) discuss the increasing importance of innovation in merger analysis. The 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines introduced a section dealing with innovation, and in the years 2013-2015, the Department of Justice challenged mergers in part due to concerns about innovation incentives in online platforms, online display advertising, chemicals, computer cir cuits, aircraft components and beer. For more see the Annual Report on Competition Policy Developments in the United States for those years, jointly produced by the DOJ and FTC.

  2. A long literature in economics considers this topic. Notably, Aghion et al. (2005) has shown a inverted-U shaped relationship between industry concentration and innovation.

  3. Hauser et al. (2006) identify innovation as “one of the most important issues in business research today.”

  4. This internalization effect is closely related to the notion of innovation markets developed by Gilbert and Sunshine (1995).

  5. This has been cited as a particularly important issue in recent pharmaceutical mergers. A notable example is the Merck purchase of Idenix in 2014.

  6. Mergers are frequently a response to a larger shock to technology, preferences or regulations that would cause firms or the entire industry to expand or contract in the absence of a merger (Harford 2005), for instance, shows that industry level merger waves are primarily driven by “economic, regulatory or technological shocks.” In addition, mergers strongly cluster over time and industries, and both the decision to merge and the decision to invest have strong strategic components that depend on rivals’ actions. These factors make finding causal evidence from pre and post-merger R&D levels very difficult. Even if a plausible instrument could be found, it is unlikely the effects of mergers induced by this instrument would be generalizable to other settings. See Nevo and Winston (2010) for more on this point. Recent attempts have been made to estimate structural models of merger dynamics, including Jeziorski (2014) in the radio industry, Igami and Uetake (forthcoming) the hard disk drive industry, Nishida and Yang (2014) in retail, and Stahl (2016) in broadcast television.

  7. Gowrisankaran (1999a) discusses the challenges of solving a dynamic model with endogenous mergers and presents a lengthy discussion of the flaws inherent in static models and models of exogenously imposed mergers.

  8. Cheong and Judd (2006) and Chen (2009) present numerical results showing that the welfare conclusions of static models can be overturned in the long run. Cheong and Judd (2006) show that even in Cournot type industries mergers may be profitable in present value terms. Each of these consider only exogenous mergers.

  9. Federico et al. (2017, 2018) study this question in a simple two-stage model. They find that mergers reduce the incentives to innovate for the merging firms, as they internalize the business stealing externality associated with innovation. This effect outweighs the increase in innovation brought about by higher post-merger profits due to the reduction in product market competition. The model does not allow for post-merger entry by new firms that may ameliorate this second effect and mergers always make consumers worse off. Similarly, Motta and Tarantino (2017) studies both quality-enhancing and cost-reducing investment incentives in a two-stage model without entry and find that mergers harm consumers if there are no corresponding efficiency gains.

  10. Specifically, Shapiro (2010) uses the definition “The prospect of gaining or protecting profitable sales by providing greater value to customers.”

  11. Shapiro (2010) calls this “arguably the most important question in the field of industrial organization.”

  12. One reason previous papers have resisted considering dynamic models of mergers in industries with more than 2 firms is that there is no fully satisfactory solution to the bargaining problem merging firms must solve due to the fact that there is a positive externality being conferred on the non-merging firm. I use the bilateral Nash bargaining outcome, effectively ignoring the effect of the merger on the non-merging firm. The externality still effects outcomes however, as firms might strategically wait or turn down a merger opportunity in cases where they would benefit more from their two rivals merging.

  13. This prevents the algorithm from getting “stuck” in non-equilibrium values. It is referred to in the machine learning literature as an epsilon-greedy or epsilon-decreasing strategy. More detail on how this is implemented can be seen in the Appendix.

  14. A similar procedure is followed by Borkovsky (2017) and Borkovsky et al. (2017).

  15. The empirical finance literature finds inconclusive results on the shares of a merger’s surplus going to either party, but most work finds the shares roughly equal. See, for instance, Ahern (2012).

  16. Because I present results for the long term stationary distribution of industry outcomes, the starting point of this simulation does not effect the results provided it is in the recurrent class. Unlike in other dynamic industry models, such as Besanko et al. (2010), there is no distinction between the short term and long term distribution of industry outcomes.

  17. As noted by Ackerberg and Rysman (2005) and others, the way taste heterogeneity is represented in logit style models means that reducing the number of products available reduces total consumer surplus, even holding all else equal.

  18. An alternative approach would be to retain multiproduct firms using the method of Gowrisankaran (1999b), although this would inevitably face an insurmountable computational limitation as firms continue to merge over time adding more and more products to their portfolios.

  19. This is distinct from how the term contestable is used by Baumol et al. (1982) who used it to referred to a market with frictionless reversible entry.

  20. For another application, see also Asker et al. (2016).

References

  • Acemoglu, D., & Akcigit, U. (2012). Intellectual property rights policy, competition and innovation. Journal of the European Economics Association, 10(1), 1–42.

  • Acemoglu, D., & Cao, D. (2015). Innovation by entrants and incumbents. Journal of Economic Theory, 157, 255–294.

  • Ackerberg, D., & Rysman, M. (2005). Unobserved product differentiation in discrete-choice models: estimating price elasticities and welfare effects. RAND Journal of Economics, 36, 771–788.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion, P., Bloom, N., Blundell, R., Griffith, R., Howitt, P. (2005). Competition and innovation: an inverted-U relationship. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120, 701–728.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ahern, K. (2012). Bargaining power and industry dependence in mergers. Journal of Financial Economics, 103, 530–550.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asker, J., Fershtman, C., Jeon, J., Pakes, A. (2016). The competitive effects of information sharing. Working Paper.

  • Baumol, W., Panzar, J., Willig, R. (1982). Contestable markets and the theory of industry structure. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besanko, D., Doraszelski, U., Kryukov, Y., Satterthwaite, M. (2010). Learning-by-doing, organizational forgetting, and industry dynamics. Econometrica, 78(2), 453–508.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borkovsky, R. (2017). The timing of version releases: a dynamic duopoly model. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 15, 187–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borkovsky, R., Doraszelski, U., Kryukov, Y. (2012). A dynamic quality ladder model with entry and exit: exploring the equilibrium correspondence using the homotopy method. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 10, 197–229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borkovsky, R., Goldfarb, A., Haviv, A., Moorthy, S. (2017). Measuring and understanding brand value in a dynamic model of brand management. Marketing Science, 36(4), 471–499.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, J. (2009). The effects of mergers with dynamic capacity accumulation. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 27, 92–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheong, K., & Judd, K. (2006). Mergers and dynamic oligopoly journal economic dynamics and control.

  • Cohen, W. (2010). Fifty years of empirical studies of innovative activity and performance. Handbook of Economics of Innovation, 1.

  • Doraszelski, U., & Pakes, A. (2008). A framework for applied dynamic analysis in I.O. The Handbook of Industrial Organization.

  • Doraszelski, U., & Satterthwaite, M. (2010). Computable Markov perfect industry dynamics. RAND Journal of Economics, 42, 215–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ericson, R., & Pakes, A. (1995). Markov-perfect industry dynamics: a framework for empirical work. Review of Economic Studies, 62, 53–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Federico, G., Langus, G., Valletti, T. (2017). A simple model of mergers and innovation. Economics Letters, 157, 136–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Federico, G., Langus, G., Valletti, T. (2018). Horizontal mergers and product innovation. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 59, 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fershtman, C., & Pakes, A. (2012). Dynamic games with asymmetric information: a framework for empirical work. Quarterly Journal Of Economics, 127(4), 1611–1661.

  • Gilbert, R. (2006). Looking for Mr. Schumpeter: where are we in the competition-innovation debate? In A. Jaffe, J. Lerner, S. Stern (Eds.) Innovation policy and the economy. Cambridge: MIT Press.

  • Gilbert, R., & Sunshine, S. (1995). Incorporating dynamic efficiency concerns in merger analysis: the use of innovation markets. Antitrust Law Journal, 63(2), 569–601.

  • Goettler, R., & Gordon, B. (2011). Does AMD Spur Intel to Innovate More? Journal of Political Economy, 119(6), 1141–1200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goettler, R., & Gordon, B. (2014). Competition and product innovation in dynamic oligopoly. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 12, 1–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gowrisankaran, G. (1999a). A dynamic model of endogenous horizontal mergers. RAND Journal of Economics, 30, 56–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gowrisankaran, G. (1999b). Efficient representation of state spaces for some dynamic models. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 23, 1077–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenstein, S., & Ramey, G. (1998). Market structure innovation, and vertical product differentiation. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 16, 285–311.

  • Harford, J. (2005). What drives merger waves? Journal of financial economics, 77, 529–560.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hauser, J., Tellis, G., Griffen, A. (2006). Research on innovation: a review and agenda for marketing science. Marketing Science, 25, 687–717.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Igami, M., & Uetake, K. (forthcoming). Mergers, innovation and entry-exit dynamics: the consolidation of the hard DIsk drive industry, pp. 1976-.2014. Working Paper.

  • Jeziorski, P. (2014). Estimation of cost synergies from mergers: application to U.S Radio. RAND Journal of Economics, 45, 37–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Judd, K. (1998). . Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz, M., & Shelanski, H. (2006). Mergers and innovation. Antitrust Law Journal, 74, 1–86.

  • Loftus, P. (2014). Merck agrees to buy idenix for $3.85 billion. The Wall Street Journal.

  • Marshall, G., & Parra, A. (2016). Innovation and competition: the role of the product market. Working paper.

  • Mermelstein, B., Nocke, V., Satterthwaite, M., Whinston, M. (forthcoming). Internal versus external growth in industries with scale economies: a computational model of optimal merger policy. Journal of Political Economy.

  • Motta, M., & Tarantino, E. (2017). The effect of horizontal mergers, when firms compete in prices and investments. Working paper department of economics and business, Universitat Pompeu Fabra.

  • Nevo, A., & Winston, M. (2010). Taking the dogma out of econometrics: structural modeling and credible inference. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 24, 69–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nishida, M., & Yang, N. (2014). Better together? Retail chain performance dynamics in store expansion before and after mergers. Working paper.

  • Pakes, A., & McGuire, P. (1994). Computing Markov perfect nash equilibria: numerical implications of a dynamic differentiated product model. RAND Journal of Economics, 25, 555–589.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pakes, A., & McGuire, P. (2001). Stochastic algorithms, symmetric Markov perfect equilibrium, and the “Curse” of dimensionality. Econometrica, 69, 1261–1281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pesendorfer, M. (2005). Mergers under entry. RAND Journal of Economics, 36, 661–679.

    Google Scholar 

  • Segal, I., & Whinston, M. (2007). Antitrust in innovative industries. American Economic Review, 97, 1703–1730.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, C. (2010). Competition and innovation: did arrow hit the bull’s eye? In J. Lerner, & S. Stern (Eds.) The rate and direction of inventive activity revisited: University of Chicago Press.

  • Stahl, J. (2016). A dynamic analysis of consolidation in the broadcast television industry. American Economic Review, 106(8), 2185–2218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I wish to thank Eugenio Miravete, Allan Collard-Wexler, Peter Rossi, Volker Nocke and audiences at the FTC Bureau of Economics and the 2015 International Industrial Organization Conference for their helpful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Brett Hollenbeck.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix: Algorithm for solving the model

Appendix: Algorithm for solving the model

This appendix describes the algorithm used to solve for an equilibrium to the model described in Section 3. This builds on the work of Pakes and McGuire (1994) and Fershtman and Pakes (2012) but adds a novel element from the reinforcement learning literature to improve convergence properties. It has been noted that the basic stochastic algorithm often performs badly on convergence. Indeed, without the changes described below the basic algorithm almost always fails to reach an equilibrium. Here I review some of the reasons for this and how they can be fixed. For greater detail on the basic algorithm see Pakes and McGuire (1994) and Fershtman and Pakes (2012).Footnote 20

The algorithm proceeds iteratively, simulating the dynamic game using a stored value function that firms use to generate policies regarding entry, exit, investment, and mergers. At each step of this simulation, the value function is updated with the payoffs realized for each action taken or not taken. The key components that are stored in memory are the current state of the industry at each iteration k, called Ωk, the stored value functions defining payoffs for each action at that state: \({W^{I}_{k}}({\Omega }_{k}, x_{i})\), \({W^{E}_{k}}({\Omega }_{k}, xe_{i})\), and \({W^{M}_{k}}({\Omega }_{k}, i,j)\), and a counter that stores the number of prior visits to state Ωk to that point: \({h^{I}_{k}}({\Omega }_{k}, x_{i})\), \({h^{E}_{k}}({\Omega }_{k}, xe_{i})\), and \({h^{M}_{k}}({\Omega }_{k}, i,j)\). If \({h^{I}_{k}}({\Omega }_{k}, x_{i})=0\), \({W^{I}_{k}}({\Omega }_{k}, x_{i})\) is empty. When the state (Ω,xi) is reached for the first time, \({W^{I}_{k}}({\Omega }, x_{i})\) is set to an initial value and updated from there.

Profits π(Ω) are computed offline for all states. Each value function is initialized at some level that I discuss in more detail below. The timing is as follows, at each iteration k:

  1. 1.

    At state Ωk draw from memory:\({W^{I}_{k}}({\Omega }_{k}, x_{i})\), \({W^{E}_{k}}({\Omega }_{k}, xe_{i})\), \({W^{M}_{k}}({\Omega }_{k}, i,j)\), \({h^{I}_{k}}({\Omega }_{k}, x_{i})\), \({h^{E}_{k}}({\Omega }_{k}, xe_{i})\), and \({h^{M}_{k}}({\Omega }_{k}, i,j)\).

  2. 2.

    For all incumbent firms i and for the potential entrant, draw investment costs \(\tilde {c_{i}}\)

  3. 3.

    Incumbents solve:

    $$ \max_{x_{i}}\{-C(\tilde{c_{i}},x_{i})+{W^{I}_{k}}({\Omega}_{k},x_{i})\} $$
    (9)

    and exits if the max of this term is less than zero. Entrants solve:

    $$ \max_{xe_{i}}\{-C(\tilde{c_{i}},xe_{i})+{W^{E}_{k}}({\Omega}_{k}, xe_{i})\} $$

    and enter if the max of this term is greater than zero.

  4. 4.

    Randomly draw the industry-wide depreciation shock η.

  5. 5.

    Using η and the investment, entry and exit decisions of incumbents and the potential entrant, update the market state from Ωk to \({\Omega }^{\prime }_{k}\).

  6. 6.

    Begin the merger stage by drawing a random ordering of firms to act as merger proposers.

  7. 7.

    Loop over all firms, for each solve for the best merger partner as \(max_{j} {W^{M}_{k}}({\Omega }^{\prime }_{k}, i,j)\). If the value of merging for both firms is higher than the option value of letting the next firm in the merger order proceed, they agree to merge, τij is calculated, \({\Omega }^{\prime }_{k}\) is updated to Ωk+ 1, and the merger stage ends. During this stage, Ωk+ 1 is necessarily rounded to the nearest integer value. Once a merger has occurred or all firms have had a chance to propose, the stage ends.

  8. 8.

    Profits for all firms are calculated as πk+ 1).

  9. 9.

    Stored value functions are updated as:

    $$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} W^{I}_{k+1}({\Omega}_{k},x^{*}_{i}) &=& \alpha^{I}({\Omega}_{k}) \beta [\pi(\omega^{\prime}_{i}) - FC + \mathbb{E} {W^{I}_{k}}({\Omega}_{k+1})]\\ &&+ (1-\alpha^{I}({\Omega}_{k}) ) {W^{I}_{k}}({\Omega}_{k},x^{*}_{i}) \end{array} $$
    (10)
    $$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} W^{E}_{k+1}({\Omega}_{k},xe^{*}_{i})&=& \alpha^{E}({\Omega}_{k}) \beta [\pi(\omega^{\prime}_{i}) - FC +\mathbb{E} {W^{I}_{k}}({\Omega}_{k+1})]\\ &&+ (1-\alpha^{E}({\Omega}_{k}) ) {W^{E}_{k}}({\Omega}_{k},xe^{*}_{i}) \end{array} $$
    (11)

    If firm i is acquired by firm j:

    $$ W^{M}_{k+1}({\Omega}^{\prime}_{k}, i,j)= \alpha^{M}({\Omega}^{\prime}_{k},i,j) \tau_{ij} + (1-\alpha^{M}({\Omega}^{\prime}_{k},i,j) ) {W^{M}_{k}}({\Omega}^{\prime}_{k}, i,j) $$
    (12)

    If firm i acquires firm j:

    $$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} W^{M}_{k+1}({\Omega}^{\prime}_{k}, i,j)&=& \alpha^{M}({\Omega}^{\prime}_{k},i,j) [ \mathbb{E} {W^{I}_{k}}({\Omega}_{k+1})-\tau_{ij} ]\\ &&+ (1-\alpha^{M}({\Omega}^{\prime}_{k},i,j) ) {W^{M}_{k}}({\Omega}^{\prime}_{k}, i,j) \end{array} $$
    (13)

    where αI(⋅), αE(⋅), and αM(⋅) are weighting functions to be described in detail below. In addition, counters \({h^{I}_{k}}\cdot )\), \({h^{E}_{k}}(\cdot )\), and \({h^{M}_{k}}(\cdot )\) are incremented by 1.

  10. 10.

    Return to step 1 at state Ωk+ 1.

The algorithm is periodically paused to test for whether an equilibrium has been reached. This test follows Fershtman and Pakes (2012) and checks whether the value functions are consistent with equilibrium notions described in Section 3.2. This simulates a sample path of the model and keeps a separate memory of the distribution of outcomes reached at each state on this sample path. The mean squared difference between these outcomes and the value function stored in memory is used to calculate bias. This is done separately for \({W^{I}_{k}}(\cdot )\), \({W^{E}_{k}}(\cdot )\), and \({W^{M}_{k}}(\cdot )\) and the highest bias value of the three is compared to .001 to determine if an equilibrium has been reached.

In most cases, this equilibrium calculation is taken inside a larger loop over possible parameter values as part of the Simple Continuation Method. This method traces out the equilibrium outcomes of the model as parameters vary. In this case, when an equilibrium is reached the value functions \({W^{I}_{k}}(\cdot )\), \({W^{E}_{k}}(\cdot )\), and \({W^{M}_{k}}(\cdot )\) are saved but the counters \(({h^{I}_{k}}\cdot )\), \({h^{E}_{k}}(\cdot )\), and \({h^{M}_{k}}(\cdot )\) are returned to 1 and the weighting functions described below are similarly updated

A key consideration in the algorithm is what function to use to weight realized payoffs in iteration k and how much to weight the current estimate of Wk(⋅). One alternative would be to simply use \(\alpha ^{I}(\cdot ) = \frac {1}{{h^{I}_{k}}({\Omega }_{k})}\), ie the number of previous visits to that state. This ultimately would give value functions equal to the arithmetic mean of realized payoffs across all visits to that state. One problem with this approach is that if the initialized value functions are far from their true values, it could take a very long time for the algorithm to converge.

A second and more serious problem with the algorithm as described above is that for discrete choices such as entry and exit, it can get “stuck” at a suboptimal choice. For example, if the value functions for firm investment are set high in order to encourage exploration, firms will initially invest large amounts and rarely exit. At the same time as they make these choices, potential entrants are exploring entry strategies and updating their entry value function with the realized outcomes. In the case where incumbents invest highly entry is rarely profitable and so in certain states potential entrants may update all entry options as having negative value. Once they have done so, entry will cease at those states and as incumbent firms investment policies converge towards equilibrium the potential entrant will have stopped testing entry even though it may be profitable to do so.

I solve this second problem by implementing a strategy from the reinforcement learning literature known as 𝜖-greedy exploration. In this case, firms will take what they perceive as being the optimal action with probability 1 − 𝜖 and with probability 𝜖 they will choose a policy at random from their set of possible actions. The researcher sets the initial value of 𝜖 to encourage exploration and as the algorithm proceeds it declines slowly to 0. In states in which firms take suboptimal policies as a result of this process, they learn and update values for those policies but the other firms in the market do not update at those states.

This approach is simple but has the advantages that it ensures each action will be taken a large number of times and that policies ultimately converge to the optimal ones. In practice, without implementing this strategy the algorithm almost always converged to an outcome where a suboptimal discrete choice was taken and which was strongly rejected as an equilibrium outcome by the testing procedure. This would remain true regardless of how long it ran. Even if this extreme case of non-convergence were not possible, it is highly likely the 𝜖-greedy exploration improves the speed to convergence of even a simple model.

1.1 A.1 Computational details

Here I provide specific details on the implementation of the algorithm. For incumbent and entrant value functions, I initialize the values above the level of discounted profits if the state they entered were permanent. A high initialization is useful for ensuring firms explore their strategy space early on. That is:

$$ {W_{0}^{I}}({\Omega}) = \frac{1.1\pi({\Omega})}{1-\beta}. $$
(14)

Merger value functions are set at a flat constant value of 5, which is high enough to encourage exploration. For all policies, 𝜖 is set initially at .1 and declines such that \(\epsilon ^{\prime } = .9\epsilon \) every 200,000 iterations.

The weighting functions used are:

$$ \alpha^{I}({\Omega}_{k})=\frac{1}{min({h^{I}_{k}}({\Omega}_{k}, x_{i}), \bar{h}^{I})} $$
(15)

where \(\bar {h}\) is a cap on high hk(⋅) for weighting purposes. This effectively places more weight on the more recent \(\bar {h}\) observations. In practice, \(\bar {h}\) begins at 100 and doubles every 1,000,000 iterations until it ceases to bind. In all cases, the test concluded that an algorithm had been reached before at most 350 million iterations and in some cases much sooner.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hollenbeck, B. Horizontal mergers and innovation in concentrated industries. Quant Mark Econ 18, 1–37 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-019-09218-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-019-09218-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation