Skip to main content
Log in

Endogenous attention to costs

  • Published:
Journal of Risk and Uncertainty Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Studies show that consumers are often unaware of the price of their purchases. We examine whether such ignorance may be willful. We develop a model entailing consumers who may feel conflicted about spending—some people have an inherent preference for overspending (“spendthrifts”). We show that if overspending causes regret, spendthrifts are better off in the short-term from ignoring costs to their consumption (i.e., prices), when ignorance reduces anticipated regret. In the long-term, ignorance of costs may, however, be harmful, since it acts to exacerbate spendthrifts’ overconsumption. Further, our model shows that consumers who are unconflicted about their spending, or have an inherent preference to underspend (“tightwads”), do not benefit from ignoring costs to their consumption in the short-term. We test the implications of our model against two datasets—a field dataset from a supermarket and data from a websurvey entailing a hypothetical experiment. We find support for our model implications that spendthrifts pay less attention to prices, and that their inattention may be endogenous (i.e., willful or strategic). Our results may help explain previous puzzling findings of low consumer price knowledge. Further, our finding that all consumer groups addressed herein have long-term benefits from price saliency provides support for policies that ensure prices are transparent and salient to consumers.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This finding is surprising, given standard economic theory. Both Wakker (1988) and Schlee (1990) show that predictions on information preferences from expected utility theory, however, crucially rely on the independence axiom.

  2. Based on survey responses by the subjects, Feldman and Ruffle (2015) conclude the systematic differences in demand responses to added taxes versus rebates are not caused by subjects’ price unawareness or cognitive price computational inabilities. They speculate their findings may be explained by consumers willfully ignoring some or all of the tax. Our study complements the price inattention studies by testing whether willful cost ignorance exists, and what consumer characteristics might explain such ignorance.

  3. Studies examining any potential regret resulting from tightwads’ underspending seem to be lacking. This lack of research may reflect an expectation that regret is less common in tightwads than spendthrifts. Overspending today likely leads to graver future consequences than does underspending. Further, spendthrifts undertake the action to spend, whereas tightwads undertake an inaction by abstaining from (additional) spending. Action, compared to inaction, has repeatedly and consistently been shown to cause higher levels of regret (Kahneman and Tversky 1982; Landman 1987; Gleicher et al. 1990).

  4. In the context of our model, hyperbolic discounting could also generate willful ignorance of costs, given that a consumer who hyperbolically (as opposed to exponentially) discounts future utility may experience a conflict between long-term and short-term spending preferences (O’Donoghue and Rabin 1999, 2003). In other contexts (e.g., preferences for timing of payment) the implications on behavior of pain and paying and time discounting may differ (see e.g., Prelec and Loewenstein 1998; Patrick and Park 2006).

  5. Although we do not formally model the reason for such regret reduction under ignorance, one reason for such reduction in negative emotions is the ability for agents to form “optimal expectations” under ignorance (see e.g., Brunnermeier and Parker 2005; Oster et al. 2013). Specifically, agents may benefit from ignorance of the state they are in, since ignorance enables them to downplay the risk of being in a “bad state,” which in turn reduces negative emotions (anxiety, worry, guilt, regret, etc).

  6. We assume no reduction in pain of paying from ignorance of costs, i.e., pain of paying (for all agents) is unaffected by ignorance. Not knowing costs may make some consumers less worried about costs. Yet it may make some people (e.g., tightwads) more worried, i.e., ignorance may cause tightwads to overestimate the risk of the consumption being high-cost, and hence increase their pain of paying. It does, however, not matter to our general findings if tightwads experience equal, or more, pain of paying under ignorance.

  7. While perhaps more common a few decades ago, priceless restaurant menus still exist (these days oftentimes upon request) in fine-dining restaurants around the world. The reason for these menus is for people not to consider meal prices when someone else in their party pays for the meal. The intent of our priceless menu is, however, that the person who avoids price information still pays for his/her own meal.

  8. Non-vegan/non-vegetarian subjects were asked to choose between the following three meal options: 1. Starter: Fresh tomato and mozzarella salad, entree: Shrimp Scampi pasta, dessert: Dark chocolate pudding, 2. Starter: Bruschetta with goat cheese and roasted pepper, entree: Sliced sirloin steak with mashed potatoes, dessert: Ice-cream cake and fresh berries, and 3. Starter: Seared garlic-lemon scallops, entree: Creamy chicken alfredo with bacon, dessert: Key lime pie. Vegan/vegetarian subjects chose between the following: 1. Starter: Shaved kale and apple salad, entree: Seared seitan cutlets with truffle mashed potatoes, dessert: Sweet rice and coconut pudding, 2. Starter: Smoked tempeh and tomato salad, entree: Roasted vegetables with truffles and quinoa, dessert: Vegan mocha cake, and 3. Starter: Roasted beet and cauliflower salad, entree: Marinated portabella mushrooms and kale with rice, dessert: Soy cheese cake.

  9. Our experimental result of 30% willfully ignorant consumers likely represents a lower bound for the prevalence of willful cost ignorance, since price information in our experiment is entirely costless, which is generally not the case in other consumer contexts. This result is also implied by previous field studies that find as many as half of consumers do not know the price of a recently purchased good, or of an item just added to their shopping cart (Allen et al. 1976; Conover 1986; Dickson and Sawyer 1990). Further, our supermarket data imply over 97% of respondents misperceive their cost of a recent purchase.

  10. Memory could impact our results, given the (albeit short) time lapse between subjects’ checkout from the supermarket and their participation in our study. A considerable body of recent research suggests salience of an attribute (such as self-selected attention to price in our study) improves memory of that attribute (see, e.g., Fine and Minnery 2009; Melcher and Piazza 2011; Santangelo 2015). An asymmetric decline in the recollection of the cost of the purchase just made over tightwads, spendthrifts and unconflicted is therefore likely to originate from heterogeneity in cost inattention, as suggested by our model. An alternative explanation would be that spendthrifts inherently have a worse memory than tightwads. Although we cannot rule that out, we also have no reason to believe that would be the case—we are unaware of any research pointing to spendthrifty consumers demonstrating worse memory. Also, the theory of spendthrifts being more motivated to pay less attention (ignore) costs, compared to tightwads and unconflicted, is supported by the results from our websurvey.

  11. Although not reported here, our supermarket data also suggests there is no significant correlation between over- or under-estimation of the total cost of a purchase just made and spendthriftiness. I.e., we do not find that spendthrifts are more likely to either over- or under-estimate the cost of their recent purchase, compared to tightwad subjects. We only find that spendthrifts are less accurate, i.e., pay less attention to costs. This is also suggested by our theoretical model.

  12. Our results are robust over the aggregation of the education dummy.

  13. In the other regressions from the websurvey, the results are so highly statistically significant that any reduced efficiency of the estimates from including professional degree goes unnoticed. Hence, for the other regressions based on this data, we report models entailing the education categories.

  14. Spendthriftiness in our websurvey is highly correlated with both the self-control measure and frugality scale, in expected ways—spendthriftier subjects have less self-control and are less frugal. This means we can be less certain our observed willful ignorance is explained by spendthriftiness per se—it may be jointly explained by self-control or frugality. Although this does not undermine our general finding of willful price ignorance, it has some implications for how to specify the theoretical model.

  15. Given that search costs are the same both for price information and price ignorance in our websurvey, someone who is completely indifferent between being informed and ignorant may be equally likely to choose ignorance and receive information about prices. To examine whether indifference is the prime motivation for any observed price avoidance, websurvey participants were surveyed on the reasons why they chose, or did not choose, to avoid price information. We surveyed both subjects in the endogenous information and the exogenous treatment, where the latter were faced with the question on whether they would have avoided price information, had they had the option. 107 subjects in the endogenous and exogenous treatments avoided price information, or stated that they would have avoided price information. Subjects could state any or all of the following reasons for avoiding price information: “I would enjoy my meal more if I didn’t have to think of the exact price.”; “Prices would not matter to my meal choice anyway.”; “As long as the price is $50 or below, the price would not matter to my meal choice.”; “I do not know”; or “Other.” The most common answer was “I would enjoy my meal more if I didn’t have to think of the exact price,” which is implied by our theory. This suggests the main reason for avoiding price information in our websurvey is not price indifference. Further, the answer to the previous question is highly correlated with being a spendthrift. If subjects chose the answer “I would enjoy my meal more if I didn’t have to think of the exact price,” the variable Price info reduces enjoyment takes the value 1, otherwise zero. The average marginal effect from a Probit regression, where the dependent variable is Price info reduces enjoyment and the dummy variables unconflicted and spendthrift are the independent variables (tightwad is baseline), shows that spendthrifts are 57.8 percentage points (P value = 0.007) more likely to choose price ignorance for the reason that it would reduce meal enjoyment, than are tightwads. Adding the same series of control variables to the regression as included in preceding regressions slightly increases the average marginal effect (to 61.5%) and decreases the P value to 0.003.

  16. We have examined the sensitivity of all results reported in this section to different cut-off values (on the STTW-scale) for the dummy variables Tightwad, Unconflicted and Spendthrift, as well as estimated all regressions using the STTW-scale, instead of the dummy variables. Our results remain robust.

References

  • Allcott, H., & Kessler, J. B. (2019). The welfare effects of nudges: A case study of energy use social comparisons. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 11(1), 236–276.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen, J. W., Harrell, G. D., & Hutt, M. D. (1976). Price awareness study. Washington, DC: The Food Marketing Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barigozzi, F., & Levaggi, R. (2010). Emotional decision-makers and anomalous attitudes towards information. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 40(3), 255–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berman, J. Z., Tran, A. T. K., Lynch, J. G., Jr., & Zauberman, G. (2016). Expense neglect in forecasting personal finances. Journal of Marketing Research, 53(4), 535–550.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broberg, T., Ellingsen, T., & Johannesson, M. (2007). Is generosity involuntary? Economics Letters, 94(1), 32–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunnermeier, M. K., & Parker, J. A. (2005). Optimal expectations. The American Economic Review, 95(4), 1092–1118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C., Issacharoff, S., Loewenstein, G., O’Donoghue, T., & Rabin, M. (2003). Regulation for conservatives: Behavioral economics and the case for “asymmetric paternalism”. University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 151(3), 1211–1254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chetty, R., Looney, A., & Kroft, K. (2009). Salience and taxation: Theory and evidence. American Economic Review, 99(4), 1145–1177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clerides, S., & Courty, P. (2017). Sales, quantity surcharge, and consumer inattention. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 99(2), 357–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conover, J. N. (1986). The accuracy of price knowledge: Issues in research methodology. In R. J. Lutz (Ed.), Advances in consumer research (Vol. 13, pp. 589–593). Ann Arbor: Association for Consumer Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Conrads, J., & Irlenbusch, B. (2013). Strategic ignorance in ultimatum bargaining. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 92, 104–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Damgaard, M. T., & Gravert, C. (2018). The hidden costs of nudging: Experimental evidence from reminders in fundraising. Journal of Public Economics, 157, 15–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dana, J., Kuang, J., & Weber, R. (2007). Exploiting moral wriggle room: Experiments demonstrating an illusory preference for fairness. Economic Theory, 33(1), 67–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dickson, P. R., & Sawyer, A. G. (1990). The price knowledge and search of supermarket shoppers. Journal of Marketing, 54(3), 42–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dittmar, H., & Drury, J. (2000). Self-image—Is it in the bag? A qualitative comparison between “ordinary” and “excessive” consumers. Journal of Economic Psychology, 21(2), 109–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckel, C. C., & Grossman, P. J. (2002). Sex differences and statistical stereotyping in attitudes toward financial risk. Evolution and Human Behavior, 23(4), 281–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldman, N. E., & Ruffle, B. J. (2015). The impact of including, adding, and subtracting a tax on demand. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 7(1), 95–118.

    Google Scholar 

  • Festinger, L. (1957). A theory of cognitive dissonance. California: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fine, M. S., & Minnery, B. S. (2009). Visual salience affects performance in a working memory task. Journal of Neuroscience, 29(25), 8016–8021.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finkelstein, A. (2009). E-ztax: Tax salience and tax rates. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(3), 969–1010.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ganguly, A., & Tasoff, J. (2016). Fantasy and dread: The demand for information and the consumption utility of the future. Management Science, 63(12), 4037–4060. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2016.2550.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gleicher, F., Kost, K. A., Baker, S. M., Strathman, A. J., Richman, S. A., & Sherman, S. J. (1990). The role of counterfactual thinking in judgments of affect. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 16(2), 284–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldin, J. (2015). Optimal tax salience. Journal of Public Economics, 131, 115–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldin, J., & Homonoff, T. (2013). Smoke gets in your eyes: Cigarette tax salience and regressivity. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 5(1), 302–336.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, Z. (2014). Strategic ignorance and the robustness of social preferences. Management Science, 60(11), 2659–2665.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, Z., & van der Weele, J. (2017). Self-image and willful ignorance in social decisions. Journal of the European Economic Association, 15(1), 173–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horváth, C., Büttner, O. B., Belei, N., & Adıgüzel, F. (2015). Balancing the balance: Self-control mechanisms and compulsive buying. Journal of Economic Psychology, 49, 120–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hossain, T., & Morgan, J. (2006) ...Plus shipping and handling: Revenue (non) equivalence in field experiments on eBay. Advances in Economic Analysis & Policy, 6, Article 3, http://www.bepress.com/bejeap/advances/vol6/iss2/art3.

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1982). The psychology of preferences. Scientific American, 246(1), 160–173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karlsson, N., Loewenstein, G., & Seppi, D. (2009). The ostrich effect: Selective attention to information. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 38(2), 95–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kőszegi, B. (2003). Health anxiety and patient behavior. Journal of Health Economics, 22(6), 1073–1084.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landman, J. (1987). Regret and elation following action and inaction: Affective responses to positive versus negative outcomes. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 13(4), 524–536.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Larson, T., & Capra, C. M. (2009). Exploiting moral wiggle room: Illusory preference for fairness? A comment. Judgment and Decision making, 4(6), 467–474.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lastovicka, J. L., Bettencourt, L. A., Hughner, R. S., & Kuntze, R. J. (1999). Lifestyle of the tight and frugal: Theory and measurement. Journal of Consumer Research, 26(1), 85–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lazear, E. P., Malmendier, U., & Weber, R. A. (2012). Sorting in experiments with application to social preferences. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 4(1), 136–163.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lichtenstein, D., Ridgway, N., & Netemeyer, R. (1993). Price perceptions and consumer shopping behavior: A field study. Journal of Marketing Research, 30(2), 234–245. https://doi.org/10.1177/002224379303000208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, G., & O’Donoghue, T. (2006). We can do this the easy way or the hard way: Negative emotions, self-regulation, and the law. University of Chicago Law Review, 73(1), 183–206.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marreiros, H., Tonin, M., Vlassopoulos, M., & Schraefel, M. C. (2017). “Now that you mention it”: A survey experiment on information, inattention and online privacy. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 140, 1–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melcher, D., & Piazza, M. (2011). The role of attentional priority and saliency in determining capacity limits in enumeration and visual working memory. PLoS One, 6(12), e29296. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0029296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Donoghue, T., & Rabin, M. (1999). Doing it now or later. American Economic Review, 89(1), 103–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Donoghue, T., & Rabin, M. (2003). Studying optimal paternalism, illustrated by a model of sin taxes. American Economic Review, 93(2), 186–191.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Guinn, T. C., & Faber, R. J. (1989). Compulsive buying: A phenomenological exploration. Journal of Consumer Research, 16(2), 147–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Onwezen, M. C., & van der Weele, C. N. (2016). When indifference is ambivalence: Strategic ignorance about meat consumption. Food Quality and Preference, 52, 96–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oster, E., Shoulson, I., & Dorsey, E. R. (2013). Optimal expectations and limited medical testing: Evidence from Huntington disease. American Economic Review, 103(2), 804–830.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Patrick, V. M., & Park, C. W. (2006). Paying before consuming: Examining the robustness of consumers’ preference for prepayment. Journal of Retailing, 82(3), 165–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pieters, R., & Zeelenberg, M. (2007). A theory of regret regulation 1.1. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 17(1), 29–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prelec, D., & Loewenstein, G. (1998). The red and the black: Mental accounting of savings and debt. Marketing Science, 17(1), 4–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rick, S. (2013). The pain of paying and tightwaddism: New insights and open questions. In S. Preston, M. Kringelbach, & B. Knutson (Eds.), The Interdisciplinary Science of Consumption. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rick, S., Cryder, C. E., & Loewenstein, G. (2008). Tightwads and spendthrifts. Journal of Consumer Research, 34(6), 767–782.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Santangelo, V. (2015). Forced to remember: When memory is biased by salient information. Behavioural Brain Research, 283, 1–10.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schlee, E. (1990). The value of information in anticipated utility theory. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 3(1), 83–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sunstein, C. R. (2019). Ruining popcorn? The welfare effects of information. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 58(2/3), 121–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tangney, J. P., Baumeister, R. F., & Boone, A. L. (2004). High self-control predicts good adjustment, less pathology, better grades, and interpersonal success. Journal of Personality, 72(2), 271–324.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taubinsky, D., & Rees-Jones, A. (2017). Attention variation and welfare: Theory and evidence from a tax salience experiment. The Review of Economic Studies, 85(4), 2462–2496.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thunström, L. (2019). Welfare effects of nudges: The emotional tax of calorie menu labeling. Judgment and Decision making, 14(1), 11–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thunström, L., Nordström, J., Shogren, J. F., Ehmke, M., & van’t Veld, K. (2016). Strategic self-ignorance. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 52(2), 117–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thunström, L., Gilbert, B., & Jones Ritten, C. (2018). Nudges that hurt those already hurting—Distributional and unintended effects of salience nudges. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 153, 267–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wakker, P. (1988). Nonexpected utility as aversion of information. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 1(3), 169–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zeelenberg, M., & Pieters, R. (2007). A theory of regret regulation 1.0. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 17(1), 3–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank Hunter Bruce for excellent research assistance. The collection of data from human subjects for this study has been approved by the IRB at University of Wyoming.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Linda Thunström.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Electronic supplementary material

ESM 1

(DOCX 73 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Thunström, L., Jones Ritten, C. Endogenous attention to costs. J Risk Uncertain 59, 1–22 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-019-09308-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-019-09308-2

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation