Skip to main content
Log in

Net neutrality and asymmetric platform competition

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Regulatory Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper we analyze the interplay between access to the last-mile network and net neutrality in the market for Internet access. We consider two competing Internet service providers (ISPs), which act as platforms between Internet users and content providers (CPs). One of the ISPs is vertically integrated and provides the other (non-integrated) ISP with access to its last-mile network. We study the impact of the access price on the termination fees charged by the ISPs to CPs for carrying their traffic. First, we show that the termination fee set by the integrated ISP decreases with the access price, whereas the termination fee of the non-integrated ISP can either increase or decrease with it. Second, we show that there exists a negative relationship (“waterbed effect”) between the access price and the total termination fee paid by the CPs. As a consequence, it may be socially optimal for the regulator to set the access price above cost when termination fees are left to the market.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, for example, Briglauer et al. (2015a) on the regulatory debates in Europe around access to “old” (copper-based) and “new” (fiber-based) local broadband infrastructures.

  2. Choi et al. (2015) also consider interconnection between ISPs, and compare a regime of net neutrality to a non-neutral regime where ISPs are allowed to price discriminate across CPs by offering them different qualities of traffic lanes. However, they consider two-way access, i.e., a reciprocal access price negotiated between symmetric (integrated) ISPs, whereas we consider one-way access between an integrated ISP and a non-integrated ISP.

  3. This asymmetry distinguishes our paper from the literature on two-way access between telecommunications networks (Laont et al. 1998 and subsequent work) and interchange fees between issuing banks of cardholders and acquiring banks of merchants (Rochet and Tirole 2002 and subsequent work).

  4. Different types of access offers exist, such as physical access (unbundling) and virtual access (bitstream access) to the integrated firm’s network.

  5. See, for example, Armstrong and Wright (2009). We use this model for its tractability. Our results are robust to alternative settings, as long as consumer participation is elastic and demand functions are symmetric and linear.

  6. In our framework, it may be socially optimal to set the access price below marginal cost, due to the imperfect competition between Internet service providers. We ignore this possibility in our analysis.

  7. The policy question that we wish to address concerns termination fees that could be charged by ISPs to CPs, so we assume that the termination fees are non-negative.

  8. If termination fees are based on traffic rather than fixed, the ISPs tend to set lower subscription fees, because high subscription fees reduce Internet traffic, which in turn reduces termination profits. The magnitude of this traffic-reduction effect increases with the level of the termination fees, which implies that there is a waterbed effect between termination fees and subscription fees. We investigated this variation of our baseline model, but it is unfortunately untractable.

  9. The detailed analysis for this case is provided in our earlier working paper, Bourreau and Lestage (2017). The case where Internet users make their participation decision before CPs does seem less relevant, but leads to similar results as well (the analysis is available upon request from the authors).

  10. The second-order conditions are always satisfied, as \(\partial ^{2}\pi _{i}/\partial p_{i}^{2}=2(\partial q_{i}/\partial p_{i})<0\).

  11. Due to their algebric complexity, we report the expressions of \(\widetilde{p_{A}}\) and \(\widetilde{p_{B}}\) in the appendix (see “Appendix A”).

  12. If we lift our assumption that access revenues should cover access costs, the regulator sets the access price below marginal cost (i.e., \(a<c_{n}\)), while maintaining the termination fees at zero.

  13. We study the relation between a regulated access price and unregulated termination fees. The other case, where the access price would be unregulated while termination fees would be regulated, does not seem relevant given the current regulatory practice.

  14. This is because indirect network effects need to be strong enough to ensure strategic complementarity, but cannot be too strong, according to the second-order condition.

  15. If termination fees are strategic complements, the total termination fees can either decrease or increase with the access price. There is a negative relation between total termination fees and the access price if \(\beta _{C}>(1+4m)\beta _{S}\) or if \(\beta _{C}\le (1+4m)\beta _{S}\) and the transportation cost h if large enough.

  16. The profit of a marginal CP that makes its content available at ISP i is given by \(\pi _{ni}=\beta _{S}{\widetilde{q}}_{i}-t_{i}-n_{i}\). The standard regularity condition is \((\partial \pi _{z1}/\partial n_{1})(\partial \pi _{z2}/\partial n_{2})-(\partial \pi _{z1}/\partial n_{2})(\partial \pi _{z1}/\partial n_{2})>0\), which can be written as \((\partial \pi _{zi}/\partial n_{i})-(\partial \pi _{zi}/\partial n_{j})<1\).

  17. In the third stage of the game, the equilibrium subscription fees are \(\widetilde{p_{A}},\widetilde{p_{B}}\) such that \(\partial \pi _{A}/\partial p_{A}=\partial \pi _{B}/\partial p_{B}=0\). The subgame perfect equilibrium subscription fees are \(p_{i}^{*}=\widetilde{p_{i}}(n_{A}^{*},n_{B}^{*})\). Then, we find that

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial p_{i}^{*}}{\partial t_{i}}=\frac{\partial \widetilde{p_{i}}}{\partial n_{i}}\frac{\partial n_{i}^{*}}{\partial t_{i}}+\frac{\partial \widetilde{p_{i}}}{\partial n_{j}}\frac{\partial n_{j}^{*}}{\partial t_{i}} \end{aligned}$$

    and

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial p_{i}^{*}}{\partial t_{j}}=\frac{\partial \widetilde{p_{i}}}{\partial n_{i}}\frac{\partial n_{i}^{*}}{\partial t_{j}}+\frac{\partial \widetilde{p_{i}}}{\partial n_{j}}\frac{\partial n_{j}^{*}}{\partial t_{j}}, \end{aligned}$$

    where \(0<-\partial \widetilde{p_{i}}/\partial n_{j}<\partial \widetilde{p_{i}}/\partial n_{i}\) and \(0<\partial n_{1}^{*}/\partial t_{2}=\partial n_{2}^{*}/\partial t_{1}<-\partial n_{1}^{*}/\partial t_{1}=-\partial n_{2}^{*}/\partial t_{2}\). It follows that \(0<\partial p_{i}^{*}/\partial t_{j}<-\partial p_{i}^{*}/\partial t_{i}\). Since by construction \(0<\partial q_{i}/\partial p_{j}<-\partial q_{i}/\partial p_{i}\), we also have \(0<\partial q_{i}^{*}/\partial t_{j}<-\partial q_{i}^{*}/\partial t_{i}\).

References

  • Armstrong, M. (2006). Competition in two-sided markets. RAND Journal of Economics, 37, 668–691.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armstrong, M., & Wright, J. (2009). Mobile call termination. Economic Journal, 119, 270–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Avenali, A., Matteucci, G., & Reverberi, P. (2010). Dynamic access pricing and investment in alternative infrastructures. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 28, 167–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bourreau, M., Kourandi, F., & Valletti, T. (2015). Net neutrality with competing internet platforms. Journal of Industrial Economics, 63, 30–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bourreau, M. & Lestage, R. (2017) Net neutrality and asymmetric platform competition. Working paper.

  • Briglauer, W., Cambini, C., & Grajek, M. (2015a). Why is Europe lagging on next generation access networks? Bruegel Policy Contribution. Issue 2015–14, September 2015. Retrieved from http://bruegel.org/publications/.

  • Briglauer, W., Frübing, S., & Vogelsang, I. (2015b). The impact of alternative public policies on the deployment of new communications infrastructure—A survey. Review of Network Economics, 13, 227–270.

    Google Scholar 

  • Broos, S., & Gautier, A. (2017). The exclusion of competing one-way essential complements: Implications for net neutrality. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 52, 358–392.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calzada, J., & Tselekounis, M. (2018). Net neutrality in a hyperlinked Internet economy. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 59, 190–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, J. P., Jeon, D.-S., & Kim, B.-C. (2015). Net neutrality, business models, and internet interconnection. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 7, 104–141.

    Google Scholar 

  • Choi, J. P., & Kim, B.-C. (2010). Net neutrality and investment incentives. RAND Journal of Economics, 41, 446–471.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D’Annunzio, A., & Russo, A. (2015). Net neutrality and internet fragmentation: The role of online advertising. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 43, 30–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeGraba, P. (2003). A bottleneck input supplier’s opportunity cost of competing downstream. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 23, 287–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Economides, N., & Hermalin, B. E. (2012). The economics of network neutrality. RAND Journal of Economics, 43, 602–629.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Economides, N., & Tåg, J. (2012). Network neutrality on the Internet: A two-sided market analysis. Information Economics and Policy, 24, 91–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gans, J. S. (2015). Weak versus strong net neutrality. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 47, 183–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gayle, P., & Weisman, D. (2007). Are input prices irrelevant for make-or-buy decisions? Journal of Regulatory Economics, 32, 195–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenstein, S., Peitz, M., & Valletti, T. (2016). Net neutrality: A fast lane to understanding the tradeoffs. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 30, 127–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jullien, B., & Sand-Zantman, W. (2018). Internet regulation, two-sided pricing, and sponsored data. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 58, 31–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kourandi, F., Krämer, J., & Valletti, T. (2015). Net neutrality, exclusivity contracts and internet fragmentation. Information Systems Research, 26, 320–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krämer, J., & Wiewiorra, L. (2012). Network neutrality and congestion sensitive content providers: Implications for content variety, broadband investment and regulation. Information Systems Research, 23, 1303–1321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krämer, J., Wiewiorra, L., & Weinhardt, C. (2013). Net neutrality: A progress report. Telecommunications Policy, 37, 794–813.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laont, J.-J., Rey, P., & Tirole, J. (1998). Network competition: I. Overview and nondiscriminatory pricing. RAND Journal of Economics, 29, 1–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mandy, D. M. (2009). Pricing inputs to induce ecient make-or-buy decisions. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 36, 29–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peitz, M., & Schuett, F. (2016). Net neutrality and inflation of traffic. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 46, 16–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reggiani, C., & Valletti, T. (2016). Net neutrality and innovation at the core and at the edge. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 45, 16–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rochet, J.-C., & Tirole, J. (2002). Cooperation among competitors: Some economics of payment card associations. RAND Journal of Economics, 33, 549–570.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sappington, D. E. M. (2005). On the irrelevance of input prices for make-or-buy decisions. American Economic Review, 95, 1631–1638.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vogelsang, I. (2003). Price regulation of access to telecommunications networks. Journal of Economic Literature, 41, 830–862.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Romain Lestage.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

We thank John Bowblis, Bruno Jullien, Fabio Manenti, Martin Peitz, Wilfried Sand-Zantman, Florian Schuett and Tommaso Valletti for helpful comments and suggestions. We also thank conference and seminar participants in Boston, Evora, Florence, and Paris.

Appendices

Appendix A: Proof of Lemma 1

The equilibrium subscription fees are as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \widetilde{p_{A}}(n_{A},n_{B})= & {} \frac{h}{1+4m}+ \frac{1+2m}{1+4m}c_{d}+\frac{4m(1+2m)}{(1+4m)(3+4m)}c_{n} \nonumber \\&+\, \frac{3+6m}{(1+4m)(3+4m)}a+\frac{2m}{1+4m}v \nonumber \\&+\,\frac{\beta _{C}}{(1+4m)(3+4m)}\left\{ \left[ 1+8m(1+m)\right] n_{A}-\left( 1+2m\right) n_{B}\right\} , \end{aligned}$$
(15)
$$\begin{aligned} \widetilde{p_{B}}(n_{A},n_{B})= & {} \frac{h}{1+4m}+\frac{1+2m}{1+4m}c_{d}+\frac{2m}{(1+4m)(3+4m)}c_{n}\nonumber \\&+\,\frac{3+8m(1+m)}{(1+4m)(3+4m)}a+\frac{2m}{1+4m}v \nonumber \\&+\,\frac{\beta _{C}}{(1+4m)(3+4m)}\left\{ \left[ 1+8m(1+m)\right] n_{B}-\left( 1+2m\right) n_{A}\right\} .\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(16)

From (15) and (16), we find that \(\partial \widetilde{p_{A}}/\partial a=(3+6m)/(3+16m+16m^{2})>0\) and \(\partial \widetilde{p_{B}}/\partial a=\left[ 3+8m(1+m)\right] /(3+16m+16m^{2})>0\). Replacing for \(\widetilde{p_{A}}\) and \(\widetilde{p_{B}}\) into \(q_{A}\) and \(q_{B}\), we find that \(\partial \widetilde{q_{A}}/\partial a=-2m(1+m)/[(3+16m+16m^{2})h]<0\) and \(\partial \widetilde{q_{B}}/\partial a=-4m(1+m)(1+2m)/[(3+16m+16m^{2})h]<0\). From (15) and (16), we have \(\partial \widetilde{p_{i}}/\partial n_{i}=\beta _{C}\left[ 1+8m(1+m)\right] /\left[ (1+4m)\left( 3+4m\right) \right] >0\) and \(\partial \widetilde{q_{i}}/\partial n_{i}=\beta _{C}(1+2m)\left[ 1+8m(1+m)\right] /\left[ 2(1+4m)\left( 3+4m\right) h\right] >0\). For \(j\ne i\), we find that \(\partial \widetilde{p_{i}}/\partial n_{j}=-\beta _{C}(1+2m)/\left[ (1+4m)\left( 3+4m\right) \right] <0\) and \(\partial \widetilde{q_{i}}/\partial n_{j}=-\beta _{C}(1+2m)^{2}/[2(1+4m)(3+4m)h]<0\).

Appendix B: Equilibrium number of CPs

The equilibrium number of CPs is as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{n^{*}}{\mu }= & {} -(t_{A}+t_{B})+\frac{(2m+1)\beta _{S}}{4m+1}- \frac{(2m(m+1)\beta _{S})}{h(4m+1)}a+\frac{(2m \beta _{S}(2m+1))}{h(4m+1)}(v-c_{d})\nonumber \\&-\, \frac{2m^{2}\beta _{S}}{h(4m+1)}c_{n}. \end{aligned}$$
(17)

The subgame perfect equilibrium subscription fees \(p_{A}^{*}\) and \(p_{B}^{*}\) are found by replacing \(n_{A}\) and \(n_{B}\) for \(n^{*}\) into (15) and (16).

Appendix C: Proof of Lemma 3

To begin with, we determine the sign of the indirect effects. For \(n_{A}=n_{B}=n\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \widetilde{p_{A}}}{\partial n}=\frac{\partial \widetilde{p_{B}}}{ \partial n}=\frac{2m\beta _{C}}{1+4m}>0\;\;\text {and\;}\;\frac{ \partial \widetilde{q_{A}}}{\partial n}=\frac{ \partial \widetilde{q_{B}}}{\partial n}=\frac{m(1+2m)\beta _{C}}{(1+4m)h}>0. \end{aligned}$$

Now, we determine the sign of \(\partial n^{*}/\partial a\). Since \(n^{*}=\beta _{S}q^{*}-t_{A}-t_{B}\),

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial n^{*}}{\partial a}=\beta _{S}\frac{\partial q^{*}}{\partial a}=\beta _{S}\left( \frac{\partial {\widetilde{q}}}{\partial a}+\frac{\partial {\widetilde{q}}}{\partial n}\frac{\partial n^{*}}{\partial a}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Therefore,

$$\begin{aligned} \left( 1-\beta _{S}\frac{\partial {\widetilde{q}}}{\partial n}\right) \frac{\partial n^{*}}{\partial a}=\beta _{S}\frac{\partial {\widetilde{q}}}{\partial a}, \end{aligned}$$

which implies that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial n^{*}}{\partial a}=\mu \beta _{S}\frac{\partial {\widetilde{q}}}{\partial a}=-\mu \beta _{S}\frac{2m(1+m)}{(1+4m)h}<0. \end{aligned}$$

The access price a has a negative direct effect and a negative indirect effect on the number of users of ISP i. Therefore, \(q_{i}^{*}\) decreases with a. By contrast, the access price has a positive direct effect and a negative indirect effect on ISP i’s subscription fee. Therefore, the effect of a on \(p_{i}^{*}\) is a priori ambiguous. We find that the equilibrium subscription fees increase with the access price for weak indirect network effects, but increase otherwise. Indeed, from (15), (16), and (17),

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial p_{A}^{*}}{\partial a}=\frac{2m\left( 2m^{2}+6m+3\right) \beta _{C}\beta _{S}-3h(2m+1)}{(4m+3)(2m(2m+1)\beta _{C}\beta _{S}-h(4m+1))} \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial p_{B}^{*}}{\partial a}=\frac{2m\left( 6m^{2}+8m+3\right) \beta _{C}\beta _{S}-h\left( 8m^{2}+8m+3\right) }{(4m+3)(2m(2m+1)\beta _{C}\beta _{S}-h(4m+1))}. \end{aligned}$$

If follows that:

  • if \(\beta _{C}\beta _{S}<h(3+6m)/(2m(3+6m+2m^{2}))\), then \(\partial p_{A}^{*}/\partial a>0\) and \(\partial p_{B}^{*}/\partial a>0\);

  • if \(h(3+6m)/(2m(3+6m+2m^{2}))\le \beta _{C}\beta _{S}<h(3+8m+8m^{2})/(2m(3+8m+6m^{2}))\), then \(\partial p_{A}^{*}/\partial a\le 0\) and \(\partial p_{B}^{*}/\partial a>0\);

  • if \(h(3+8m+8m^{2})/(2m(3+8m+6m^{2}))\le \beta _{C}\beta _{S}<h(1+4m)/(2m(1+2m))\), then \(\partial p_{A}^{*}/\partial a<0\) and \(\partial p_{B}^{*}/\partial a<0\).

Appendix D: Proof of Proposition 1

1.1 Expressions for welfare

We denote by \(w_{S}\) the welfare on the service side, and by \(w_{C}\) the welfare on the content side. Total welfare is then \(w\equiv w_{S}+w_{C}\). We have

$$\begin{aligned} w_{S}= & {} \intop _{0}^{{\hat{x}}^{*}}(v+\beta _{C}n^{*}-hx)dx+\intop _{{\hat{x}}^{*}}^{1}(v+\beta _{C}n^{*}-h(1-x))dx+ \\&\quad m\intop _{0}^{{\hat{x}}_{A}^{*}}(v+\beta _{C}n^{*}-hx)dx+m\intop _{0}^{{\hat{x}}_{B}^{*}}(v+\beta _{C}n^{*}-hx)dx+n^{*}(t_{A}+t_{B})-cq^{*}, \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} w_{C}=\intop _{0}^{n^{*}}(\beta _{S}q^{*}-t_{A}-t_{B}-y)dy. \end{aligned}$$

We find that

$$\begin{aligned} w_{S}= & {} (v+\beta _{C}n^{*}-c)q^{*}-(({\hat{x}}_{A}^{*})^{2}+({ \hat{x}}_{B}^{*})^{2})mh/2\nonumber \\&-(({\hat{x}}^{*})^{2}+(1-{\hat{x}}^{*})^{2})h/2+ n^{*}(t_{A}+t_{B}) \end{aligned}$$
(18)

and that

$$\begin{aligned} w_{C}=\beta _{S}q^{*}n^{*}-(t_{A}+t_{B})n^{*}-(n^{*})^{2} /2=(n^{*})^{2}/2. \end{aligned}$$
(19)

1.2 Variations of welfare with termination fees

From (18) and (19), using the fact that \(v+\beta _{C}n^{*}-h{\hat{x}}_{i}^{*}=p_{i}^{*}\) and that \(\partial p_{B}^{*}/\partial t_{i}=\partial p_{A}^{*}/\partial t_{i}\), after some computations we find that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial w}{\partial t_{A}}{=}\beta _{C}q^{*}\frac{\partial n^{*}}{\partial t_{A}}+(t_{A}+t_{B})\frac{\partial n^{*}}{\partial t_{A}}+\beta _{S}n^{*}\frac{\partial q^{*}}{\partial t_{A}}+\frac{m}{h}\underset{i=A,B}{\sum }(p_{i}^{*}-c) \left( \beta _{C}-\frac{\partial \widetilde{p_{i}}}{\partial n^{e}}\right) \frac{\partial n^{*}}{\partial t_{A}}. \end{aligned}$$

First, we have \(\partial n^{*}/\partial t_{A}<0\) and \(\partial q^{*}/\partial t_{A}<0\) from Lemma 2. Second, we find that \(\beta _{C}-(\partial \widetilde{p_{i}}/\partial n^{e})=(1+2m)\beta _{C}/(1+4m)>0\). Therefore, \(\partial w/\partial t_{A}<0\). Similarly, we have \(\partial w/\partial t_{B}<0\).

1.3 Variations of welfare with access price

First, we have \(\partial w_{C}/\partial a=n^{*}\partial n^{*}/\partial a<0.\) Second, from (18) and (19), computations show that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial w_{S}}{\partial a}= & {} \beta _{C}q^{*}\frac{\partial n^{*}}{\partial a}+m(p_{A}^{*}-c)\frac{\partial {\hat{x}}_{A}^{*}}{\partial a}+m(p_{B}^{*}-c)\frac{\partial {\hat{x}}_{B}^{*}}{\partial a}+ \nonumber \\&\quad (t_{A}+t_{B})\frac{\partial n^{*}}{\partial a}-\left( {\hat{x}}^{*}-\frac{1}{2}\right) \left( \frac{\partial p_{B}^{*}}{\partial a}-\frac{\partial p_{A}^{*}}{\partial a}\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(20)

To show that \(\partial w_{S}/\partial a<0\), first note that \(\partial n^{*}/\partial a<0\) from Lemma 3. Since the number of CPs and the subscription fees decrease with a, then \(\partial {\hat{x}}_{i}^{*}/\partial a<0.\) Finally, we have \(\partial \widetilde{p_{B}}/\partial a>\partial \widetilde{p_{A}}/\partial a\) from “Appendix A”, and \(\partial \widetilde{p_{B}}/\partial n^{e}=\partial \widetilde{p_{A}}/\partial n^{e}\). Therefore, \(\partial p_{B}^{*}/\partial a>\partial p_{A}^{*}/\partial a\). It follows that the term \(-({\widetilde{x}}^{*}-1/2)\left( \partial p_{B}^{*}/\partial a-\partial p_{A}^{*}/\partial a\right) \) is negative, since \({\widetilde{x}}^{*}>1/2\). This shows that \(\partial w_{S}/\partial a<0\).

Appendix E: Proof of Lemma 4

We first determine the second-order conditions (i), and then study under which condition the termination fees are strategic substitutes or complements (ii).

(i) The first-order conditions of profit maximization with respect to termination fees are

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _{A}^{*}}{\partial t_{A}}=q_{A}^{*}\frac{\partial p_{A}^{*}}{\partial t_{A}}+(p_{A}^{*}-c)\frac{\partial q_{A}^{*}}{\partial t_{A}}+(a-c_{n})\frac{\partial q_{B}^{*}}{\partial t_{A}}+\frac{\partial n^{*}}{\partial t_{A}}t_{A}+n^{*}=0, \end{aligned}$$
(21)

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _{B}^{*}}{\partial t_{B}}=q_{B}^{*}\frac{\partial p_{B}^{*}}{\partial t_{B}}+(p_{B}^{*}-a-c_{d})\frac{\partial q_{B}^{*}}{\partial t_{B}}+\frac{\partial n^{*}}{\partial t_{B}}t_{B}+n^{*}=0. \end{aligned}$$
(22)

Using (21) and (22) and the fact that \(n^{*}\), \(p_{i}^{*}\), and \(q_{i}^{*}\) are linear in the termination fees, we find that the second-order conditions are satisfied if and only if

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^{2}\pi _{A}^{*}}{\partial t_{A}^{2}}=\frac{\partial ^{2}\pi _{B}^{*}}{\partial t_{B}^{2}}=2\left( \frac{\partial q_{A}^{*}}{\partial t_{A}}\frac{\partial p_{A}^{*}}{\partial t_{A}}+\frac{\partial n^{*}}{\partial t_{A}}\right) \equiv Z<0. \end{aligned}$$
(23)

Let \(X\equiv (\partial p_{A}^{*}/\partial t_{A})(\partial q_{A}^{*}/\partial t_{A})\) and \(Y\equiv \partial n^{*}/\partial t_{A}\). From Lemma 2, we have \(X>0\) and \(Y<0\). Therefore, we have \(Z=2(X+Y)<0\) iff \(X<-Y\).

(ii) Now, assume that the SOC holds, i.e., \(Z<0\). Using (21) and (22) and the fact that \(\partial p_{i}^{*}/\partial t_{i}=\partial p_{j}^{*}/\partial t_{i}\), \(\partial q_{i}^{*}/\partial t_{i}=\partial q_{j}^{*}/\partial t_{i}\), and \(\partial n^{*}/\partial t_{A}=\partial n^{*}/\partial t_{B}\), we have, from the implicit function theorem,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial t_{A}^{BR}}{\partial t_{B}}=\frac{\partial t_{B}^{BR}}{\partial t_{A}}=-\frac{1}{Z}\left( 2\frac{\partial q_{A}^{*}}{\partial t_{A}}\frac{\partial p_{A}^{*}}{\partial t_{A}}+\frac{\partial n^{*}}{\partial t_{A}}\right) =\frac{2X+Y}{-Z}. \end{aligned}$$
(24)

The termination fees are strategic substitutes if \(\partial t_{A}^{BR}/\partial t_{B}<0\), i.e., if \(X<-Y/2\), and strategic complements otherwise.

To sum up, termination fees are strategic substitutes if \(X\in \left[ 0,-Y/2\right] \), and strategic complements if \(X\in \left( -Y/2,-Y\right) \). We find that \(X<-Y/2\) iff \(h>{\widetilde{h}}\) with \({\widetilde{h}}\equiv 2m(1+2m)(\beta _{S}+2m(\beta _{C}+2\beta _{S}))\beta _{C}/(1+4m)^{2}\) and \(X<-Y\) iff \(h>{\widehat{h}}\) with \({\widehat{h}}\equiv (2m(1+2m)(\beta _{S}+m(\beta _{C}+4\beta _{S}))\beta _{C}/(1+4m)^{2}\). It follows that the termination fees are strategic complements for \(h\in \left( {\widehat{h}},{\widetilde{h}}\right) \) and strategic substitutes for \(h\ge {\widetilde{h}}\). Finally, note that \({\widetilde{h}}\) increases in \(\beta _{S}\) and \(\beta _{C}\). Therefore, for a given value of h, the termination fees are strategic substitutes if \(\beta _{S}\) and/or \(\beta _{C}\) are small enough.

Appendix F: Proof of Lemma 5

We find that \(\partial t_{A}^{BR}/\partial a=AT\) and \(\partial t_{B}^{BR}/\partial a=BT\), where

$$\begin{aligned} A\equiv & {} -h,(3+4m(3+4m))\beta _{C}-h(1+4m)(3+4m)\beta _{S}\\&+\,6m( \beta _{C}+2\beta _{C}m)^{2}\beta _{S}+2m(1+2m)(3+4m)\beta _{C}\beta _{S}^{2}, \\ \quad B\equiv & {} -4m^{2}(1+2m)\beta _{S}\beta _{C}^{2}-h(1+4m)(3+4m) \beta _{S}\\&+\,2m(1+2m)(4h+(3+4m)\beta _{C}\beta _{S}^{2}), \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} T\equiv \frac{m(1+m)}{h(3+4m)\left( h(1+4m)^{2}-2m(1+2m)(cm+ \beta _{S}+4m\beta _{S})\beta _{C}\right) }. \end{aligned}$$

From the SOC, T is positive. Furthermore, A is decreasing in h and negative at \(h={\widetilde{h}}\). Therefore, \(\partial t_{A}^{BR}/\partial a<0\). We also have \(B>0\) at \(h={\widetilde{h}}\) and \(\partial B/\partial h=8m(\beta _{C}+2m\beta _{C}-2\beta _{S}(m+1))-3\beta _{S}\), which is positive iff \(\beta _{C}>\beta _{S}(4m+1)(4m+3)/\left[ 8m(2m+1)\right] \equiv {\widetilde{\beta }}_{C}\). Therefore, if \(\beta _{C}>{\widetilde{\beta }}_{C}\), then \(B>0\) always holds and if \(\beta _{C}\le {\widetilde{\beta }}_{C}\), we have \(B>0\) for low values of h and \(B\le 0\) otherwise. If follows that \(\partial t_{B}^{BR}/\partial a>0\) if \(\beta _{C}>{\widetilde{\beta }}_{C}\), or if \(\beta _{C}\le {\widetilde{\beta }}_{C}\) and h is low enough. Otherwise, \(\partial t_{B}^{BR}/\partial a<0\).

Finally, we find that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial t_{B}^{BR}}{\partial a}-\frac{\partial t_{A}^{BR}}{\partial a}=(8m+3)\beta _{C}\left[ h(1+4m)-2\beta _{C}\beta _{S}m(2m+1)\right] T, \end{aligned}$$

which is positive from the SOC. Therefore, an increase in the access price decreases more the best response of ISP A than the best response of ISP B.

Appendix G: Proof of Proposition 2

From “Appendices E” and “F”, we infer the derivatives of the equilibrium termination fees with respect to the access price. Indeed, for all \(i,j\in \{A,B\}\) and \(i\ne j\),

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial t_{i}^{*}}{\partial a}=\left( \frac{\partial t_{i}^{BR}}{\partial a}+\frac{\partial t_{i}^{BR}}{\partial t_{j}}\frac{\partial t_{j}^{BR}}{\partial a}\right) /\left( 1-\frac{\partial t_{i}^{BR}}{\partial t_{j}}\frac{\partial t_{j}^{BR}}{\partial t_{i}}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

We calculate \(\partial t_{A}^{*}/\partial a\) and find that it is equal to a fraction. Its denominator is positive from the second-order condition for the termination fees. The derivative of the numerator with respect to h is equal to \(-2m(1+m)(1+4m)\left[ 2(3+8m(2+3m))\beta _{C}+3\beta _{S}+16m(1+m)\beta _{S}\right] \), and therefore it is negative, which shows that the numerator is decreasing in h. Since the numerator is strictly negative at \(h={\widetilde{h}}\), it is negative for all h. Therefore, we have \(\partial t_{A}^{*}/\partial a<0\).

We proceed in the same way for \(\partial t_{B}^{*}/\partial a\). We find that it is equal to a fraction whose denominator is positive from the second-order condition. The numerator is strictly positive at \(h={\widetilde{h}}\). It is increasing in h if \(\beta _{C}>(1+4m)(3+4m)\beta _{S}/[3+4m(7+12m)]\). If this condition holds, the numerator is always positive and \(\partial t_{B}^{*}/\partial a>0\). If the condition on \(\beta _{C}\) does not hold, the numerator is positive for low values of h, and negative otherwise. In this case, we have \(\partial t_{B}^{*}/\partial a>0\) for low values of h, and \(\partial t_{B}^{*}/\partial a<0\) for high values of h.

Finally, we find that

$$\begin{aligned} t_{A}^{*}-t_{B}^{*}=-\frac{2(a-c_{n})m(1+m)(3+8m)\beta _{C}}{h(1+4m)(3+4m)}. \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, we have \(t_{A}^{*}<t_{B}^{*}\) if \(a>c_{n}\), and \(t_{A}^{*}=t_{B}^{*}\) if \(a=c_{n}\).

Appendix H: Proof of Proposition 3

We find that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d(t_{A}^{*}+t_{B}^{*})}{da}=\frac{2m(1+m)((\beta _{C}+2 \beta _{S}+8m\beta _{S})h-2m(1+2m)(\beta _{C}+2\beta _{S}) \beta _{C}\beta _{S})}{(2m(1+2m)(3\beta _{S}+4m( \beta _{C}+3\beta _{S}))\beta _{C}-3(1+4m)^{2}h)h}. \end{aligned}$$

The second-order condition for the termination fee-setting game (i.e., \(h>{\widehat{h}}\); see “Appendix E”) implies that the denominator is negative. The numerator is increasing in h, and it is strictly positive at \(h={\widetilde{h}}\); hence it is positive for all h. This proves that \(d(t_{A}^{*}+t_{B}^{*})/da<0\).

Appendix I: Proof of Proposition 4

From the definitions of welfare on the service and the content side (see “Appendix D”, (18) and (19)), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dW}{da}=(n^{**}+\beta _{C}q^{**}+t^{*})\frac{\partial n^{**}}{\partial a}+m(p_{A}^{**}-c)\frac{\partial {\hat{x}}_{A}^{**}}{\partial a}+m(p_{B}^{**}-c)\frac{\partial {\hat{x}}_{B}^{**}}{\partial a}+ \end{aligned}$$
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial t*}{\partial a}n^{**}-\left( {\hat{x}}^{**}-\frac{1}{2}\right) \left( \frac{\partial p_{B}^{**}}{\partial a}-\frac{\partial p_{A}^{**}}{\partial a}\right) , \end{aligned}$$
(25)

where the superscript “**” indicates that the prices, quantities, and locations of the indifferent consumers are evaluated at the equilibrium termination fees.

The first term on the second line of (25) is negative. It corresponds to the decrease in the ISPs’ total termination revenue, which follows from the decrease in the total termination fee (see Proposition 3). The second term on the second line represents a consumption misallocation effect on the service side and is also negative. Indeed, from the definition of the equilibrium subscription and termination fees, we find that \(p_{B}^{**}-p_{A}^{**}=2(a-c_{n})m/(3+4m)\) and, therefore, \({\hat{x}}^{**}\ge 1/2\) and \(\partial p_{B}^{**}/\partial a-\partial p_{A}^{**}/\partial a>0\). The first term on the first line of (25) is positive iff \(\partial n^{**}/\partial a>0\). Finally, at \(a=c_{n}\), we have \(p_{A}^{**}=p_{B}^{**}\) and, therefore, \(m(p_{A}^{**}-c)(\partial {\hat{x}}_{A}^{**}/\partial a)+m(p_{B}^{**}-c)(\partial {\hat{x}}_{B}^{**}/\partial a)>0\) iff \(\partial q^{**}/\partial a>0\). This proves that, to have \(dW/da>0\) in the neighborhood of \(a=c_{n}\), it is necessary that either \(\partial n^{**}/\partial a>0\) or \(\partial q^{**}/\partial a>0\).

We find that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial q^{**}}{\partial a}=\frac{2m(m+1)(2m(2m+1)(\beta _{C}+2\beta _{S}) \beta _{C}-3h(4m+1))}{h\left( 3h(4m+1)^{2}-2m(2m+1)(4m( \beta _{C}+3\beta _{S})+3\beta _{S})\beta _{C}\right) } \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial n^{**}}{\partial a}=\frac{2m(m+1)((1+4m)\beta _{S}-\beta _{C})}{2m(2m+1)(4m(\beta _{C}+3\beta _{S})+3 \beta _{S})\beta _{C}-3h(4m+1)^{2}}. \end{aligned}$$

It follows that \(\partial q^{**}/\partial a>0\) iff \(4\beta _{C}\beta _{S}+2\beta _{C}^{2}>3h\left( \frac{2}{2m+1}+\frac{1}{m}\right) \). We also find that \(\partial n^{**}/\partial a>0\) iff \(\beta _{C}>(1+4m)\beta _{S}\).

Fig. 4
figure 4

Range of parameters in \((h,\beta _{C})\) space that satisfy assumptions

Fig. 5
figure 5

Socially-optimal access price as a function of \(\beta _{C}\)

Appendix J: Proof of Proposition 5

For our numerical simulations, we make the following assumptions. To ensure that all users located on the Hotelling line subscribe to an ISP for a wide range of parameter values, we assume that the utility derived from Internet access is high enough, namely \(v=5\). We normalize the network effects originating from the service side to \(\beta _{S}=1\) and let the network effects originating from the content side \(\beta _{C}\) vary between 0 and 3 / 2. We set the mass of Internet users in the hinterlands to \(m=1\) and let the transportation cost h vary between 1 and 5. Finally, we assume that the marginal cost of the last-mile network and the retail marginal cost are equal to zero: \(c_{n}=c_{d}=0\).

In Fig. 4, the colored area represents the range of parameters such that Assumption 2 is satisfied, welfare is concave in the access price, and the subscription fees, the termination fees, the number of CPs, the number of Internet users, and the utility of the users located on the Hotelling line are non-negative. We observe that \(h=3\) and \(\beta _{C}\in [0,1.15]\) belongs to this range of parameters and use these specific parameter values to draw Fig. 5.

Figure 5 shows the socially-optimal access price as a function of the degree of externality \(\beta _{C}\) for the case studied in the main model and for the extension presented in Sect. 6 (Internet fragmentation). The two cases are represented by the plain curve and the dashed curve, respectively. As for the main case, we observe that the socially-optimal access price is higher than the marginal cost \(c_{n}=0\) for all \(\beta _{C}\) between 0 and about 1.12, which proves Proposition 5.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bourreau, M., Lestage, R. Net neutrality and asymmetric platform competition. J Regul Econ 55, 140–171 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-019-09380-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-019-09380-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation