Skip to main content
Log in

An alternative to natural monopoly

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Regulatory Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We consider a shared ownership arrangement among consumers/owners as a means to organize production with an underlying decreasing average cost function typical of natural monopolies. The resulting output allocation yields a lower deadweight loss than the monopoly allocation, and is, in some cases, efficient.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For the definition of subadditive costs, see, e.g., Braeutigam (1989).

  2. See, e.g., Khan (2016).

  3. This cost efficiency argument must account for the deadweight loss from monopoly, which acts as a countervailing force.

  4. Consider the case of Pacific Gas and Electric Company, the investor-owned utility headquartered in San Francisco, and its handling of recent fire threats in California by employing sweeping power outages.

  5. Consider planned obsolescence in market economies, a phenomenon that is hard to sustain under shared ownership by consumers/users.

  6. The behavioral assumption matters even in the case when consumer decisions have a limited effect on ownership shares (as would be the case here if n were ‘large,’ i.e., if consumers were ‘small’ relative to the size of the market), in the sense that, in our framework, equilibrium outcomes differ from those that would obtain in a ‘Walrasian-like’ setting where consumers ignore the ownership effect.

  7. Recall that the average cost curve is decreasing.

  8. If the assumption that each consumer i’s surplus for the first unit consumed exceeds \(\textit{AC}(\sum _{j\ne i}{\hat{x}}_j)\) is not fulfilled, then the consumers will not demand good x. More precisely, only consumers for which the said assumption holds will consume good x. If no one values the good enough to pay its average cost, production will not take place, solving Coase’s problem.

  9. As an example, consider the production function \(f(l,k)=lk^2\), which exhibits increasing returns to scale (resp. constant returns to scale) with respect to labor and capital (resp. labor).

References

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Oriol Carbonell-Nicolau.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

I wish to thank Tomas Sjöström, an anonymous referee, and the journal’s editor for valuable comments.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Carbonell-Nicolau, O. An alternative to natural monopoly. J Regul Econ 58, 184–192 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-020-09416-x

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-020-09416-x

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation