Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Infrastructure and general purpose technologies: a technology flow framework

  • Published:
European Journal of Law and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Studies of economic growth often refer to “general purpose technology” (GPT), “infrastructure,” and “openness” as keys to improving productivity. Some GPTs, like railroads and the Internet, fit common notions of infrastructure and spawn debates about openness, such as network neutrality. Other GPTs, like the steam engine and the computer, seem to be in a different group that is more modular and open by nature. Big data, artificial intelligence, and various emerging smart technological assemblages have been described both as GPTs and infrastructure. We present a technology flow framework that clarifies when a GPT is implemented through infrastructure, provides a basis for policy analysis, and defines empirical research questions. On the demand side, all GPTs—whether implemented through infrastructure or not—enable a wide variety of productive uses and generate substantial spillovers to the rest of the economy. On the supply side, infrastructure is different from many other implementations of GPTs; infrastructure is partially nonrival, which may complicate appropriation problems and raise congestion issues. It also exhibits tethering, meaning that different users must be physically or virtually connected for the infrastructure to function, and this makes control of its uses more feasible and more salient to policy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. While we are primarily focused on positive third-party effects, we note that negative effects are also possible, for example when transportation infrastructure facilitates illegal movements of goods or when Internet infrastructure facilitates divisive or mental-health-impairing forms of social media. Where such effects exist, they further heighten the pressure for some form of overarching commons management of the infrastructure.

  2. With respect to national and regional economic growth, Gramlich (1994, p. 1177) defines infrastructure as “large capital-intensive natural monopolies such as highways, other transportation facilities, water and sewer lines, and communication systems,” and Grimes (2014, p. 333) expands it to “capital-intensive investments that service multiple users.” Frischmann (2012) develops the idea of infrastructural resources that are a special type of public good that has three characteristics.

  3. The facility is a specific part or group of parts of what Lipsey et al. (2005) call the facilitating structure of technology.

  4. Frischmann also discusses purely nonrival “intellectual infrastructure,” but our model in this paper does not aim to incorporate those examples.

  5. As always, one can further subdivide, and say that computers are built on microprocessors, storage devices, and so forth. Older GPTs like electricity and even the wheel (on the mouse or disk drive) play a role in computers.

  6. An even more pure example of rival production would be Adam Smith’s pin factory, where the user of a pin would not need any design or support services at all.

  7. Apparently the first reference to this term is Ramsdell (1980) regarding the VisiCalc spreadsheet.

  8. The adjective working is important here. One could have a non-working copy of Excel even without a computer, just as one could have a non-working car without an internal combustion engine.

  9. In most cases that we are aware of, the owners of a facility seem to perceive benefits from being labeled infrastructure, since this implies that the facility is more worthy of attention and perhaps favorable policy treatment through regulation or even subsidies. However, if the label “infrastructure” is seen as implying social or regulatory obligations (more like “public utility”), facility owners might resist it.

  10. There is a downside to this openness, since it enables uses that may produce negative third-party effects that are both legal (transportation of cigarettes or transmission of pornography) or illegal (transportation of illegal weapons or hacking of personal information). These negative third-party effects can lead both to call for policing while keeping the system open (the usual response with roads) or to calls for the system to be made less open (e.g. requiring Facebook to detect factually incorrect information).

  11. This term seems to have been first used by Vint Cerf, David Reed, Stephen Crocker, Lauren Weinstein and Daniel Lynch in an Oct. 2009 letter to then FCC Chairman Julius Genochowski supporting network neutrality: http://voices.washingtonpost.com/posttech/NetPioneersLettertoChairmanGenachowskiOct09.pdf.

  12. Increasingly there are field-of-use restrictions in licensing agreements that legally “tether” the technology to certain uses (Schuett 2012).

  13. Carlaw et al. (2008) present a different view that there is one overall GPT called “programmable computing networks” of which computers and the Internet are just separate implementations. They also argue that the term ICT should properly be even broader, encompassing writing systems, printing, and so forth since these also facilitate communication of information.

References

  • Aghion, P., David, P. A., & Foray, D. (2009). Science, technology and innovation for economic growth: Linking policy research and practice in ‘stig systems’. Research Policy, 38(4), 681–693.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arthur, W. B. (2009). The nature of technology: What it is and how it evolves. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aschauer, D. A. (2000). Public capital and economic growth: Issues of quantity, finance, and efficiency. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 48(2), 391–406.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bauer, J. M. (2014). Platforms, systems competition, and innovation: Reassessing the foundations of communications policy. Telecommunications Policy, 38(8–9), 662–673.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bekar, C., Carlaw, K., & Lipsey, R. (2018). General purpose technologies in theory, application and controversy: A review. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 28, 1005–1033.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boudreau, K. J., & Hagiu, A. (2009). Platform rules: Multi-sided platforms as regulators. London: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bresnahan, T. F., & Trajtenberg, M. (1995). General purpose technologies ‘engines of growth’? Journal of Econometrics, 65(1), 83–108.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cardona, M., Kretschmer, T., & Strobel, T. (2013). ICT and productivity: Conclusions from the empirical literature. Information Economics and Policy, 25(3), 109–125.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlaw, K. I., & Lipsey, R. G. (2002). Externalities, technological complementarities and sustained economic growth. Research Policy, 31(8), 1305–1315.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlaw, K. I., Lipsey, R. G., & Webb, R. (2008). Has the ICT revolution run its course? International Congress on Environmental Modeling and Software, 262, 200–212.

    Google Scholar 

  • David, P. A. (1990). The dynamo and the computer: An historical perspective on the modern productivity paradox. The American Economic Review, 80(2), 355–361.

    Google Scholar 

  • David, P. A., & Foray, D. (1996). Information distribution and the growth of economically valuable knowledge: A rationale for technological infrastructure policies. In M. Teubal, D. Foray, M. Justman, & E. Zuscovitch (Eds.), Technological infrastructure policy (pp. 87–116). Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • FCC. (2010). 2010 open internet order. FCC 10-201, December 23, 2010.

  • FCC. (2015). 2015 open internet order. FCC 15-24, March 12, 2015.

  • Feldman, M. P., & Yoon, J. W. (2011). An empirical test for general purpose technology: An examination of the cohen–boyer rdna technology. Industrial and Corporate Change, 21(2), 249–275.

    Google Scholar 

  • Field, A. J. (2011). A great leap forward: 1930s depression and US economic growth. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frischmann, B. M. (2012). Infrastructure: The social value of shared resources. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frischmann, B. M., & Hogendorn, C. (2015). Retrospectives: The marginal cost controversy. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 29(1), 193–206.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frischmann, B. M., & Lemley, M. A. (2007). Spillovers. Columbia Law Review, 107(1), 257–301.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frischmann, B., & Selinger, E. (2018). Re-engineering humanity. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghosh, A., & Meagher, K. (2004). Political economy of infrastructure investment: A spatial approach. North American Econometric Society Summer Meetings, Brown University.

  • Gramlich, E. M. (1994). Infrastructure investment: A review essay. Journal of Economic Literature, 32(3), 1176–1196.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grimes, A. (2014). Infrastructure and regional economic growth. Handbook of Regional Science, 331–352.

  • Helpman, E. (1998). Introduction. In E. Helpman (Ed.), General purpose technologies and economic growth, Cambridge. MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E., & Trajtenberg, M. (1998). Diffusion of general purpose technologies. In E. Helpman (Ed.), General purpose technologies and economic growth (pp. 85–119). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hess, C., & Ostrom, E. (2003). Ideas, artifacts, and facilities: Information as a common-pool resource. Law and Contemporary Problems, 66(1/2), 111–145.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hogendorn, C. (2005). Regulating vertical integration in broadband: Open access versus common carriage. Review of Network Economics, 4(1), 19–32.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hogendorn, C. (2012). Spillovers and network neutrality. In G. Faulhaber, G. Madden, & J. Petchey (Eds.), Regulation and the performance of communication and information networks (pp. 191–208). London: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jovanovic, B., & Rousseau, P. L. (2005). General purpose technologies. Handbook of Economic Growth, 1, 1181–1224.

    Google Scholar 

  • Justman, M., & Teubal, M. (1995). Technological infrastructure policy (tip): Creating capabilities and building markets. Research Policy, 24(2), 259–281.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liao, H., Wang, B., Li, B., & Weyman-Jones, T. (2016). Ict as a general-purpose technology: The productivity of ICT in the United States revisited. Information Economics and Policy, 36, 10–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liebowitz, S. J., & Margolis, S. E. (1994). Network externality: An uncommon tragedy. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(2), 133–150.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lipsey, R., Carlaw, K., & Bekar, C. (2005). General purpose technologies and long-term economic growth. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, K. M., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1989). Industrialization and the big push. Journal of Political Economy, 97(5), 1003–1026.

    Google Scholar 

  • National Research Council. (1987). Infrastructure for the 21st century: Framework for a research agenda. Washington, DC: National Academy Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Odlyzko, A. (2003). Privacy, economics, and price discrimination on the internet. In Proceedings of the 5th international conference on electronic commerce (pp. 355–366), ACM.

  • Odlyzko, A. (2004). The evolution of price discrimination in transportation and its implications for the internet. Review of Network Economics, 3(3), 323–346.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V., & Ostrom, E. (1977). Public goods and public choices. In E. S. Savas (Ed.), Alternatives for delivering public services: Toward improved performance (pp. 7–49). Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Plantin, J.-C., Lagoze, C., Edwards, P. N., & Sandvig, C. (2016). Infrastructure studies meet platform studies in the age of Google and Facebook. New Media & Society., 20, 293–310.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramsdell, R. E. (1980). The power of VisiCalc. BYTE, November, 190–192.

  • Rosenberg, N. (1978). Inside the black box: Technology and economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenstein-Rodan, P. N. (1943). Problems of industrialisation of Eastern and South-Eastern Europe. The Economic Journal, 53(210/211), 202–211.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schuett, F. (2012). Field-of-use restrictions in licensing agreements. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 30(5), 403–416.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steinmueller, W. E. (1996). Technological infrastructure in information technology industries. In M. Teubal, D. Foray, M. Justman, & E. Zuscovitch (Eds.), Technological infrastructure policy: An international perspective (pp. 117–139). Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Strahilevitz, L. J. (2005). Information asymmetries and the rights to exclude. Michigan Law Review, 104, 1835.

    Google Scholar 

  • Venturini, F. (2015). The modern drivers of productivity. Research Policy, 44(2), 357–369.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zittrain, J. (2008). The future of the internet—And how to stop it. New York: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Christiaan Hogendorn.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hogendorn, C., Frischmann, B. Infrastructure and general purpose technologies: a technology flow framework. Eur J Law Econ 50, 469–488 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-020-09642-w

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-020-09642-w

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation