Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Does enfranchisement affect fiscal policy? Theory and empirical evidence on Brazil

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Economics of Governance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies the effect of political participation on public spending at the local level in Brazil. In particular, we look at the phased-in implementation of electronic voting in the late 1990s—which enfranchised poorer voters by decreasing the number of invalid votes—to identify the causal effect of political participation on public spending. We build a theoretical political economy model which allows voters to cast, not purposefully, an invalid vote, and show that when poorer voters’ likelihood of casting a valid vote increases, public social spending increases as well. We test this prediction empirically using a difference-in-differences model where municipalities using electronic voting constitute our treatment group. We find that an increase of 1 percentage point in the valid vote to turnout ratio for state representatives increases health spending by 1.8%; education by 1.4%; public employment by 1.25%; intergovernmental transfers by 1%; and local taxes by 2.6%.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In Fujiwara (2015), the Brazilian states are the unit of analysis and the impact of poor citizens’ enfranchisement is measured against health spending and health outcomes only.

  2. For empirical research measuring the effect of voting costs on electoral outcomes, see, for instance, Lott (2009) and Schneider and Senters (2018).

  3. Both municipal and federal elections grant a 4-years terms to the ones elected (except senators that get 8-year terms). In addition, a 2 years distance separates these two elections.

  4. These 57 municipalities had more than 200,000 voters, which is significantly more than the municipal average number of voters in Brazil at the time—just over 16,000 voters—, and are therefore excluded from our analysis.

  5. It is also important to note that the government, at the time, produced TV ads that taught voters how to vote using the new system and trained people to help voters if something went wrong during the voting process in the election day.

  6. There is a large literature that explains people’s decision to vote. The motives include a sense of civic duty (Blais and Young 1999), group peer presure (Schram and Van Winden 1991; Schram and Sonnemans 1996), altruism (Edlin et al. 2007), and ethics rules (Feddersen and Sandroni 2006).

  7. Alternatively, and more precisely, we could consider \(\kappa _i\) to be an additional cost the citizen has to incur in order to cast a valid vote, in a mandatory voting regime.

  8. For the sake of simplicity, we rule away the possibility of a purposeful blank vote as a political statement, i.e., in the present model, a citizen will cast an invalid vote only if she/he decides not to incur the cost of preparing for voting.

  9. See Ferejohn (1986), Bugarin (1999) or Bugarin (2003) for a discussion on the “sociotropic” (economic) versus “ideological” components of a voter’s utility function.

  10. Analogous results would be obtained if we had set the bias with respect to party A due to the symmetry of the bias.

  11. See “Poll Analyses”, Section “Gallup Poll News Service”, The Gallup Organization, http://www.gallup.com, 09/24/2001.

  12. See Fujiwara (2015) or Hidalgo (2012), for example, or the data available at the Brazilian Superior Electoral Court (http://www.tse.jus.br).

  13. The Brazilian National Treasury publishes detailed annual municipal expenditures. All variables on spending are in per capita values and have been deflated using the IGPM index (1994 is the base year).

  14. See Ferreira and Bugarin (2007), Brollo and Nannicini (2012), and Bugarin and Marciniuk (2017).

  15. As we show in the Appendix, Table 6, valid votes to turnout ratio for municipal councils were also positively affected by EV usage.

  16. Blank votes are votes cast on purpose for no candidates by pressing a white button on the electronic voting machine. Null votes are votes that are cast to a candidate that does not exist (i.e., to cast a null vote, one should type a number that represents no candidate and press the green button to confirm).

  17. If we were to consider all municipalities that used EV in 1998, our treatment group would have municipalities where the number of eligible voters would vary from 947 to 7,131,342. On the other hand, the control group would have, at most, 40,499 eligible voters.

  18. See Angrist and Krueger (1999) for a complete discussion on the DID methodology.

  19. Fujiwara (2015) explains the selection of the four states as follows: “Two remote states largely covered by the Amazon forest (Amapá and Roraima) were chosen to check the electoral authority’s ability to distribute EV in isolated areas, while the states of Rio de Janeiro and Alagoas had areas where the army provided security to election officials, allowing an opportunity to check the logistics of distributing the electronic devices jointly with the military” (p. 431).

  20. According to IBGE (the Brazilian institute of geography and statistics), municipalities with less than 5,000 citizens, between 1998 and 2000, got on average 57.3% of their revenue from FPM.

  21. Bugarin and Marciniuk (2017) also conclude for the neutrality of the FPM in their study of partisan transfers in Brazil.

  22. This assumes that the increase in public spending caused by EV is solely driven by enfrnachisement in legislative elections. If one considers the federal representatives’ elections instead, then the conclusion would be that an increase of 1 percentage point in the valid vote to turnout ratio for federal representatives increases health spending by 1.13%; education by 0.9%; public employment by 0.81%; intergovernmental transfer by 0.63%; and local taxes by 1.63%.

  23. This table is available upon request.

  24. A parametric fuzzy RDD estimation, which considers the entire sample of municipalities, reports an increase close to 11 percentage points in the number of valid votes to turnout ratio for municipal representatives due to the EV usage. This estimation is similar to the one reported in Table 6 considering only the State of São Paulo.

References

  • Alesina AF, Giuliano P (2011) Preferences for redistribution. Handb Soc Econ 1:93–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angrist JD, Krueger AB (1999) Empirical strategies in labor economics. Handb Labor Econ 3:1277–1366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berinsky A (2005) The perverse consequences of electoral reform in the United States. Am Polit Res 33(4):471–491

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berinsky A, Burns M, Traugott M (2001) Who votes by mail?: A dynamic model of the individual-level consequences of voting-by-mail systems. Public Opin Q 65(2):178–197

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhatt R, Dechter E, Holden R (2019) Registration costs and voter turnout. https://sites.google.com/site/edechter/research

  • Blais A, Young R (1999) Why do people vote? An experiment in rationality. Public Choice 99(1–2):39–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Braconnier C, Dormagen J, Pons V (2017) Voter registration costs and disenfranchisement: experimental evidence from France. Am Polit Sci Rev 111(3):584–604

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brollo F, Nannicini T (2012) Tying your enemy’s hands in close races: the politics of federal transfers in Brazil. Am Polit Sci Rev 106(4):742–761

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown DS, Hunter W (1999) Democracy and social spending in Latin America, 1980–92. Am Polit Sci Rev 93(4):779–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bugarin M (1999) Vote splitting as insurance against uncertainty. Public Choice 98(1):153–169

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bugarin M (2003) Vote splitting, reelection and electoral control: towards a unified model. Soc Choice Welf 20(1):137–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bugarin M, Marciniuk F (2017) Strategic partisan transfers in a federation: evidence from a new Brazilian database. J Appl Econ 20(2):211–239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bugarin M, Portugal A (2015) Should voting be mandatory? The effect of compulsory voting rules on candidates’ political platforms. J Appl Econ 18(1):1–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cascio EU, Washington E (2013) Valuing the vote: the redistribution of voting rights and state funds following the voting rights act of 1965. Q J Econ 129(1):379–433

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs A (1957) Who votes by mail? An economic theory of democracy. Harper and Row, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Edlin A, Gelman A, Kaplan N (2007) Voting as a rational choice: why and how people vote to improve the well-being of others. Ration Soc 19(3):293–314

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feddersen T, Sandroni A (2006) A theory of participation in elections. Am Econ Rev 96(4):1271–1282

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferejohn J (1986) Incumbent performance and electoral control. Public Choice 50(1):5–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferreira IFS, Bugarin M (2007) Transferências voluntárias e ciclo político-orçamentário no federalismo fiscal brasileiro. Revista Brasileira de Economia 61(3):271–300

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujiwara T (2015) Voting technology, political responsiveness, and infant health: evidence from Brazil. Econometrica 83(2):423–464

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujiwara T, Meng K, Vogl T (2016) Habit formation in voting: evidence from rainy elections. AEJ Appl Econ 8(4):160–188

    Google Scholar 

  • Hassell H, Settle J (2017) The differential effects of stress on voter turnout. Polit Psychol 38(3):533–550

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hidalgo FD (2012) Renovating democracy: the political consequences of election reforms in post-war Brazil. Dissertation, UC Berkeley

  • Hodler R, Luechinger S, Stutzer A (2015) The effects of voting costs on the democratic process and public finances. AEJ Econ Policy 7(1):141–171

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman M, Len G, Lombardi M (2017) Compulsory voting, turnout, and government spending: evidence from Austria. J Public Econ 145:103–115

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Husted TA, Kenny LW (1997) The effect of the expansion of the voting franchise on the size of government. J Polit Econ 105(1):54–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kleven HJ, Landais C, Saez E, Schultz E (2014) Migration and wage effects of taxing top earners: evidence from the foreigners’ tax scheme in Denmark. Q J Econ 129(1):333–378

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindert PH (2004) Growing public: volume 1, the story: social spending and economic growth since the eighteenth century. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lott J (2009) Non-voted ballots, the cost of voting, and race. Public Choice 138(1):171–97

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer AH, Richard SF (1981) A rational theory of the size of government. J Polit Econ 89(5):914–927

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mendes M, Miranda RB, Cosio FB (2008) Transfêrencias Intergovernamentais no Brasil: Diagnóstico e Proposta de Reforma. Consultoria Legislativa do Senado Federal, Textos Para Discussão 40

  • Mueller DC, Stratmann T (2003) The economic effects of democratic participation. J Public Econ 87(9):2129–2155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Novaes LM (2018) Disloyal brokers and weak parties. Am Polit Sci Rev 62(1):84–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ricker W, Ordeshook P (1968) A theory of the calculus of voting. Am Polit Sci Rev 62(1):25–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider R, Senters K (2018) Winners and losers of the ballot: electronic vs. traditional paper voting systems in Brazil. Latin Am Polit Soc 60(2):41–60

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider R, Athias D, Bugarin M (2019) Electronic voting and public spending: the impact of enfranchisement on federal budget amendments in Brazil. J Appl Econ (accepted)

  • Schram A, Sonnemans J (1996) Why people vote: experimental evidence. J Econ Psychol 17(4):417–442

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schram A, Van Winden F (1991) Why people vote: free riding and the production and consumption of social pressure. J Econ Psychol 12(4):575–620

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are very grateful to the co-editor, Marko Koethenbuerger, and the anonymous referee for their insightful comments and suggestions. We also thank Rebecca Thornton, Daniel Bernhardt, Daniel McMillen, Jake Bowers, José Cheibub for their detailed feedback and support. This paper also benefited from comments by participants at the 9th Midwest Graduate Student Summit in Applied Economics, Regional and Urban Studies; the 2016 Midwest International Economic Development Conference; the 2016 LACEA-LAMES Annual Meeting; the 2017 North American Summer Meeting of the Econometric Society; the 2017 European Meeting of the Econometric Society; the 45th ANPEC Annual Conference and the UIUC graduate seminars. All errors are our own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Rodrigo Schneider.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Schneider, R., Athias, D. & Bugarin, M. Does enfranchisement affect fiscal policy? Theory and empirical evidence on Brazil. Econ Gov 20, 389–412 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-019-00230-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-019-00230-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation