Skip to main content
Log in

Net Stable Funding Ratio and Liquidity Hoarding

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Schmalenbach Business Review Aims and scope

Abstract

As a component of the liquidity requirements of Basel III, the Net Stable Funding Ratio (NSFR) seeks to limit the maturity transformation of banks. This paper examines whether the NSFR affects the inefficient precautionary liquidity hoarding of banks and the stability of interbank markets. Based on Acharya and Skeie (2011), the model introduces regulation into a two-period framework with asymmetric information and stochastic credit risk. As a result, due to regulatory costs, the NSFR increases the bid-ask spread on the interbank market. The effects depend strongly on the quality and the forbearance of the regulator. High-quality supervision counters the precautionary liquidity hoarding of banks resulting from asymmetric information, thereby decreasing market failure.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. By assumption, equity is the most expensive form of funding (e.g. \(i_{E}> r\)). Thus, the bank will provide equity capital backing for regulatory reasons only.

  2. A further discussion of the banks’ objective function and the role of equity in the model can be found in Appendix B.

  3. The assumption about the same success probability \(\theta\) for both investment projects is less restrictive than it may appear at first glance. The parameter \(\theta\) may be interpreted as the probability of success of an investment of one risk class in the banking sector. Such an assumption does not presume that the success probabilities of both projects are correlated.

  4. Note that including an additional solvency constraint would simply increase the probability of a non-binding NSFR because the effects of the NSFR and a risk-weighted solvency constraint point in the same direction.

  5. Risk shifting can be interpreted as a decrease in risk management of the investment, which according to the NSFR requires a higher RSF factor. (See Acharya and Skeie 2011, p. 439 f.)

  6. A detailled discussion about why banks face insolvency when being incited to engage in risk shifting can be found in Appendix C.

References

  • Acharya, V.V., and O. Merrouche. 2012. Precautionary hoarding of liquidity and interbank markets: Evidence from the subprime crisis. Review of Finance 17:107–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acharya, V.V., and D. Skeie. 2011. A model of liquidity hoarding and term premia in inter-bank markets. Journal of Monetary Economics 58:436–447.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acharya, V.V., H.S. Shin, and T. Yorulmazer. 2010. Crisis resolution and bank liquidity. Review of Financial Studies 24:2166–2205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allen, F., and D. Gale. 2004. Financial intermediaries and markets. Econometrica 72:1023–1061.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allen, F., E. Carletti, and D. Gale. 2009. Interbank market liquidity and central bank intervention. Journal of Monetary Economics 56:639–652.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashcraft, A., J. McAndrews, and D. Skeie. 2011. Precautionary reserves and the interbank market. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 43:311–348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • BCBS. 2014. Basel III: the net stable funding ratio. http://www.bis.org/bcbs/publ/d295.pdf. Accessed 2 Aug 2018.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dermine, J. 1986. Deposit rates, credit rates and bank capital: The Klein-Monti model revisited. Journal of Banking and Finance 10:99–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, D.W., and A.K. Kashyap. 2016. Liquidity requirements, liquidity choice, and financial stability. Handbook of Macroeconomics, Vol. 2, 2263–2303. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Farhi, E., M. Golosov, and A. Tsyvinski. 2009. A theory of liquidity and regulation of financial intermediation. Review of Economic Studies 76:973–992.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gale, D., and T. Yorulmazer. 2013. Liquidity hoarding. Theoretical Economics 8:291–324.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein, M.A. 1971. A theory of the banking firm. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 3:205–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monti, M. 1972. Deposit, credit, and interest rate determination under alternative bank objectives. Mathematical Methods in Investment and Finance 1:431–454.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myers, S.C., and N.S. Majluf. 1984. Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have. Journal of Financial Economics 13:187–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pausch, T., and P. Welzel. 2013. Regulation, credit risk transfer with cds, and bank lending. Credit and Capital Markets 46:439–465.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perotti, E., and J. Suarez. 2011. A pigovian approach to liquidity regulation. International Journal of Central Banking 7:3–41.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I am grateful to Udo Broll, Hans-Peter Burghof, Hartmut Egger, Thomas Gehrig, Claudia Kuehne, Gabriel Lee, Thilo Pausch, Regina T. Riphahn, Eva Schliephake, Mohamed Shaban and Peter Welzel for useful comments. I also acknowledge input from the seminar particpants at the ICBFP (Famagusta), the BGPE research workshop (Bayreuth), the EARIE (Maastricht), the GEABA (Hohenheim), the workshop “Banks and Financial Markets” of the Deutsche Bundesbank (Eltville), the IFABS (Porto) and the WIEM (Warsaw) and two anonymous reviewers.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Martin Windl.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Appendix A: Balance Sheet Considerations

1.1.1 Laissez-faire

Banks of type \(L\) fund with time deposits TD and demand deposits DD (Table 2).

Table 2 Bank \(L\) in \(t_{0}\)

Banks of type \(L\) use the hoarded liquidity to mitigate the funding gap in \(t_{1}\) (Table 3).

Table 3 Bank \(L\) in \(t_{1}\)

Banks of type \(B\) use the interbank borrowing \(b\) to increase their investment position (Table 4).

Table 4 Bank \(B\) in \(t_{0}\) and \(t_{1}\)

1.1.2 NSFR regulation

Long-term lending \(l\) to the interbank market requires a bank of type \(L\) to adjust its balance sheet. In particular, when the NSFR is a binding constraint, the bank has to raise additional costly equity \(c_{E}^{L}\) to hold a liquidity buffer \(\textit{Cash}_{\textit{NSFR}}\) (Table 5).

Table 5 Bank \(L\) in \(t_{0}\)

A bank of type \(L\) must not use its liquidity \(\textit{Cash}_{\textit{NSFR}}\) in \(t_{1}\) to mitigate the funding gap in \(t_{1}\), which results from withdrawn demand deposits, because otherwise the bank would violate the NSFR (Table 6).

Table 6 Bank \(L\) in \(t_{1}\)

Borrowing \(b\) from the interbank market requires a bank of type \(B\) to adjust its balance sheet. In particular, when the NSFR is a binding constraint, the bank has to raise additional costly equity \(c_{E}^{B}\) and hold a liquidity buffer \(\textit{Cash}_{\textit{NSFR}}\). Long-term borrowing \(b\) from the interbank market decreases the regulatory pressure, resulting from the difference between the RSF from investing additional units into the investment project and the ASF from borrowing from the interbank market (Table 7).

Table 7 Bank \(B\) in \(t_{0}\) and \(t_{1}\)

1.2 Appendix B: Banks’ Objective Function and The Role of Equity

The equity costs in this framework result from agency problems between the bank management and the shareholders. This approach is based on Myers and Majluf (1984) and Pausch and Welzel (2013).

In this model, the bank management acts in the old shareholders’ interest, assuming that those shareholders do not adjust their portfolios in response the banks’ decisions. Thus, maximizing \(E(\pi)\) implies acting in the old shareholders’ interest. The high costs of new shareholders \(i_{E}> r\) result from asymmetric information in this framework.

By assumption, the bank management has an informational advantage about the value of the long-term investment towards the shareholders. Since the value of the project is private information, the market is not willing to compensate the banks for this information. Thus, issuing new shares would be a “bad” signal concerning the value of a bank’s project. This in turn lowers the price that new shareholders are willing to pay for the issue. Thus, issuing new shares comes at a cost for old shareholders. In the model these costs exceed the positive net present value of the project.

As shown in Appendix A, in order to meet the regulatory constraint of the NSFR, the banks raise costly equity \(c_{E}^{B}i_{E}\) and \(c_{E}^{L}i_{E}\) from new shareholders to hold additional liquidity.

The regulatory mechanism presented here is very similar to a solvency constraint. Alternative adjustment processes to meet the NSFR would be possible. However, since leaving the optimum due to regulation always decreases \(E(\pi)\), alternative adjustments do not change the results qualitatively.

1.3 Appendix C: Incentive Constraint

The bank is not viable when being incited to engage in risk shifting because the demand depositors withdraw their amount of DD in \(t_{1}\). In this case, demand depositors are better off when withdrawing in \(t_{1}\):

1.3.1 (Expected) pay-off structure without risk shifting:

$$\text{Return per unit}=\begin{cases}1,&\text{if the demand depositor withdraws}\\ \theta{f_{L}}=1,&\text{if the demand depositor prolongs funding}\end{cases}$$
(35)

The banks of type \(L\) choose \(f_{L}\) (or respectively banks of type \(B\) choose \(f_{B}\)) in \(t_{1}\) in a way to make the demand depositors indifferent between withdrawing and prolonging funding in \(t_{1}\).

1.3.2 (Expected) pay-off structure with risk shifting:

However, when the banks are incited to engage in risk shifting, the actual (expected) pay-off structure for the demand depositors changes as follows:

$$\text{Return per unit}=\begin{cases}1,&\text{if the demand depositor withdraws}\\ \theta_{R}{f_{L}}<1,&\text{if the demand depositor prolongs funding}\end{cases}$$
(36)

Hence, demand depositors are strictly better off by withdrawing in \(t_{1}\) instead of leaving their money in the bank until \(t_{2}\) because the demand depositors are liable but not participate in case of success.

Consequently, a bank faces insolvency in \(t_{1}\) because it is not possible to prolong funding via demand deposits to close the bank’s funding gap. Moreover, equity it is too expensive due to asymmetric information as discussed in Appendix B.

1.4 Appendix D: Comparative Statics

1.4.1 Maximization problem of bank \(L\) in case b):

$$\begin{array}[]{l}\max_{l}E(\pi)=\int_{\hat{\theta}^{L}}^{\overline{\theta}}\bigg[\theta\left(y+lr-\dfrac{\rho_{L_{\textit{TD}}}}{1+i_{\textit{TD}}}i_{\textit{TD}}-i_{E}\left(\gamma\dfrac{y}{1+i_{I}}+\delta{l}-\alpha\textit{DD}-\beta\dfrac{\rho_{L_{\textit{TD}}}}{1+i_{\textit{TD}}}\right)\right)\\ \quad\quad-\big(DD-(1-l)\big)\bigg]g(\theta)\mathrm{d}{\theta}\end{array}$$
(37)

The necessary and sufficient conditions are given by the following:

$$\begin{aligned}\displaystyle\begin{array}[]{rl}\dfrac{\partial{E(\pi)}}{\partial{l}}=&\int_{\hat{\theta}^{L}}^{\overline{\theta}}[\theta(r-i_{E}\delta)-1]g(\theta)\mathrm{d}{\theta}\\ &-\left[\hat{\theta}^{L}lr+k^{L}\left(1-\dfrac{\gamma_{R}}{1+i_{I_{R}}}i_{E}\right)\right]g(\hat{\theta}^{L})\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{L}}{\partial l}=0\\ {\dfrac{\partial^{2}{E({\pi})}}{\partial{l}^{2}}}=&-\left[\hat{\theta}^{L}r+\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{L}}{\partial l}lr\right]g(\hat{\theta}^{L})\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{L}}{\partial l}\\ &-\left[\hat{\theta}^{L}lr+k^{L}\left(1-\dfrac{\gamma_{R}}{1+i_{I}}i_{E}\right)\right]g^{\prime}(\hat{\theta}^{L})\left(\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{L}}{\partial l}\right)^{2}\\ &-\left[\hat{\theta}^{L}lr+k^{L}\left(1-\dfrac{\gamma_{R}}{1+i_{I_{R}}}i_{E}\right)\right]g(\hat{\theta}^{L})\dfrac{\partial^{2}\hat{\theta}^{L}}{\partial l^{2}}<0\end{array}\end{aligned}$$

1.4.2 Comparative statics:

$$\dfrac{d{l}}{{dk^{L}}}=-\dfrac{{\dfrac{\partial^{2}{E({\pi})}}{\partial{l}\partial{k^{L}}}}}{{\dfrac{\partial^{2}{E({\pi})}}{\partial{l}^{2}}}}\leq 0$$
(38)

The partial derivative of the first-order condition with respect to \(k^{L}\) is given by the following:

$$\begin{array}[]{rl}{\dfrac{\partial^{2}{E({\pi})}}{\partial{l}\partial{k^{L}}}}=&{-(\hat{\theta}^{L}(r-i_{E}\delta)-1)g(\hat{\theta}^{L})\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{L}}{\partial k^{L}}}\\ &-\left[\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{L}}{\partial k^{L}}lr+\left(1-\dfrac{\gamma_{R}}{1+i_{I_{R}}}i_{E}\right)\right]g(\hat{\theta}^{L})\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{L}}{\partial k^{L}}\leq 0\end{array}$$
(39)

Moral hazard mitigates interbank lending \(l\), ceteris paribus.

1.5 Appendix E: Comparative Statics

1.5.1 Maximization problem of bank \(L\) in case c):

$$\max_{l}E(\pi)=\int_{\hat{\theta}^{L}}^{\overline{\theta}}\left[\theta\left(y+lr-\dfrac{\rho_{L_{\textit{TD}}}}{1+i_{\textit{TD}}}i_{\textit{TD}}\right)-(DD-(1-l))\right]g(\theta)\mathrm{d}{\theta}$$
(40)

The necessary and sufficient conditions are as follows:

$$\begin{aligned}\displaystyle\begin{array}[]{rl}\dfrac{\partial{E(\pi)}}{\partial{l}}&=\int_{\hat{\theta}^{L}}^{\overline{\theta}}[\theta r-1]g(\theta)\mathrm{d}{\theta}\\ &\quad-\left[\hat{\theta}^{L}lr+k^{L}\left(1-\dfrac{\gamma_{R}}{1+i_{I_{R}}}i_{E}\right)\right]g(\hat{\theta}^{L})\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{L}}{\partial l}=0\\ {\dfrac{\partial^{2}{E({\pi})}}{\partial{l}^{2}}}&=-\left[\hat{\theta}^{L}r+\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{L}}{\partial l}lr\right]g(\hat{\theta}^{L})\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{L}}{\partial l}\\ &\quad-\left[\hat{\theta}^{L}lr+k^{L}\left(1-\dfrac{\gamma_{R}}{1+i_{I}}i_{E}\right)\right]g^{\prime}(\hat{\theta}^{L})\left(\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{L}}{\partial l}\right)^{2}<0\end{array}\end{aligned}$$

1.5.2 Comparative statics:

$$\dfrac{d{l}}{{dk^{L}}}=-\dfrac{{\dfrac{\partial^{2}{E({\pi})}}{\partial{l}\partial{k^{L}}}}}{{\dfrac{\partial^{2}{E({\pi})}}{\partial{l}^{2}}}}\leq 0$$
(41)

The partial derivative of the first-order condition with respect to \(k^{L}\) is given by the following:

$$\begin{array}[]{rl}{\dfrac{\partial^{2}{E({\pi})}}{\partial{l}\partial{k^{L}}}}=&{-(\hat{\theta}^{L}r-1)g(\hat{\theta}^{L})\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{L}}{\partial k^{L}}}\\ &-\left[\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{L}}{\partial k^{L}}lr+\left(1-\dfrac{\gamma_{R}}{1+i_{I_{R}}}i_{E}\right)\right]g(\hat{\theta}^{L})\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{L}}{\partial k^{L}}\leq 0\end{array}$$
(42)

Moral hazard mitigates interbank lending \(l\), ceteris paribus.

The results of the comparative statics for case b) in Eq. (38) and for case c) in Eq. (41) are valid if and only if banks are regulated by an informed regulator. The NSFR mitigates the moral hazard problem because it imposes regulatory costs \(\dfrac{\gamma_{R}}{1+i_{I_{R}}}i_{E}\) on risk shifting for the banks.

1.6 Appendix F: Comparative Statics

1.6.1 Maximization problem of bank \(B\) in case b):

$$\begin{array}[]{rl}\max_{b}E(\pi)=&\int_{\hat{\theta}^{B}}^{\overline{\theta}}\Bigg[\theta\left(y+b(y-r)-i_{E}\left(\gamma(1+b)-\delta{b}-\alpha\textit{DD}-\beta\dfrac{\rho_{B_{\textit{TD}}}}{1+i_{\textit{TD}}}\right)\right)\\ &-\textit{DD}\Bigg]g(\theta)\mathrm{d}{\theta}\end{array}$$
(43)

The necessary and sufficient conditions with \(g^{\prime}(\hat{\theta}^{B})=0\) are as follows:

$$\begin{array}[]{rl}{\dfrac{\partial{E({\pi})}}{\partial{b}}}=&\int_{\hat{\theta}^{B}}^{\overline{\theta}}\left[\theta(y-r-i_{E}(\gamma-\delta))\right]g(\theta)\mathrm{d}{\theta}\\ &-\left[k^{B}(1+b)\left(1-\dfrac{\gamma_{R}}{1+i_{I_{R}}}i_{E}\right)\right]g({\hat{\theta}}^{B})\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{B}}{\partial b}=0\\ {\dfrac{\partial^{2}{E({\pi})}}{\partial{b^{2}}}}=&-[{\hat{\theta}}^{B}(y-r-i_{E}(\gamma-\delta))]g({\hat{\theta}}^{B})\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{B}}{\partial b}\\ &-\left[k^{B}\left(1-\dfrac{\gamma_{R}}{1+i_{I_{R}}}i_{E}\right)\right]g({\hat{\theta}}^{B})\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{B}}{\partial b}\\ &-\left[k^{B}(1+b)\left(1-\dfrac{\gamma_{R}}{1+i_{I_{R}}}i_{E}\right)\right]g({\hat{\theta}}^{B})\dfrac{\partial^{2}\hat{\theta}^{B}}{\partial b^{2}}<0\end{array}$$
(44)

1.6.2 Comparative statics:

$$\dfrac{d{b}}{{dk^{B}}}=-\dfrac{{\dfrac{\partial^{2}{E({\pi})}}{\partial{b}\partial{k^{B}}}}}{{\dfrac{\partial^{2}{E({\pi})}}{\partial{b}^{2}}}}\leq 0$$
(45)

The partial derivative of the first-order condition with respect to \(k^{B}\) is given by the following:

$$\begin{array}[]{rl}{\dfrac{\partial^{2}{E({\pi})}}{\partial{b}\partial{k^{B}}}}=&-[{\hat{\theta}}^{B}(y-r-i_{E}(\gamma-\delta))]g({\hat{\theta}}^{B})\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{B}}{\partial k^{B}}\\ &-\left[(1+b)\left(1-\dfrac{\gamma_{R}}{1+i_{I_{R}}}i_{E}\right)\right]g({\hat{\theta}}^{B})\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{B}}{\partial b}\\ &-\left[k^{B}(1+b)\left(1-\dfrac{\gamma_{R}}{1+i_{I_{R}}}i_{E}\right)\right]g({\hat{\theta}}^{B})\dfrac{\partial^{2}\hat{\theta}^{B}}{\partial b\partial k^{B}}\leq 0\end{array}$$
(46)

Moral hazard mitigates interbank borrowing \(b\), ceteris paribus.

1.7 Appendix G: Comparative Statics

1.7.1 Maximization problem of bank \(B\) in case c):

$$\max_{b}E(\pi)=\int_{\hat{\theta}^{B}}^{\overline{\theta}}\big[\theta\left(y+b(y-r)\right)-\textit{DD}\big]g(\theta)\mathrm{d}{\theta}$$
(47)

The necessary and sufficient conditions with \(g^{\prime}(\hat{\theta}^{B})=0\) are given by the following:

$$\begin{array}[]{rl}{\dfrac{\partial{E({\pi})}}{\partial{b}}}=&\int_{\hat{\theta}^{B}}^{\overline{\theta}}\left[\theta(y-r)\right]g(\theta)\mathrm{d}{\theta}\\ &-\left[k^{B}(1+b)\left(1-\dfrac{\gamma_{R}}{1+i_{I_{R}}}i_{E}\right)\right]g({\hat{\theta}}^{B})\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{B}}{\partial b}=0\\ {\dfrac{\partial^{2}{E({\pi})}}{\partial{b^{2}}}}=&-[{\hat{\theta}}^{B}(y-r)]g({\hat{\theta}}^{B})\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{B}}{\partial b}\\ &-\left[k^{B}\left(1-\dfrac{\gamma_{R}}{1+i_{I_{R}}}i_{E}\right)\right]g({\hat{\theta}}^{B})\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{B}}{\partial b}\\ &-\left[k^{B}(1+b)\left(1-\dfrac{\gamma_{R}}{1+i_{I_{R}}}i_{E}\right)\right]g({\hat{\theta}}^{B})\dfrac{\partial^{2}\hat{\theta}^{B}}{\partial b^{2}}<0\end{array}$$
(48)

1.7.2 Comparative statics:

$$\dfrac{d{b}}{{dk^{B}}}=-\dfrac{{\dfrac{\partial^{2}{E({\pi})}}{\partial{b}\partial{k^{B}}}}}{{\dfrac{\partial^{2}{E({\pi})}}{\partial{b}^{2}}}}\leq 0$$
(49)

The partial derivative of the first-order condition with respect to \(k^{B}\) is as follows:

$$\begin{array}[]{rl}{\dfrac{\partial^{2}{E({\pi})}}{\partial{b}\partial{k^{B}}}}=&-[{\hat{\theta}}^{B}(y-r)]g({\hat{\theta}}^{B})\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{B}}{\partial k^{B}}\\ &-\left[(1+b)\left(1-\dfrac{\gamma_{R}}{1+i_{I_{R}}}i_{E}\right)\right]g({\hat{\theta}}^{B})\dfrac{\partial\hat{\theta}^{B}}{\partial b}\\ &-\left[k^{B}(1+b)\left(1-\dfrac{\gamma_{R}}{1+i_{I_{R}}}i_{E}\right)\right]g({\hat{\theta}}^{B})\dfrac{\partial^{2}\hat{\theta}^{B}}{\partial b\partial k^{B}}\leq 0\end{array}$$
(50)

Moral hazard mitigates interbank borrowing \(b\), ceteris paribus.

The results of the comparative statics for case b) in Eq. (45) and for case c) in Eq. (49) are valid if and only if banks are regulated by an informed regulator. The NSFR mitigates the moral hazard problem because it imposes regulatory costs \(\dfrac{\gamma_{R}}{1+i_{I_{R}}}i_{E}\) on risk shifting for the banks.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Windl, M. Net Stable Funding Ratio and Liquidity Hoarding. Schmalenbach Bus Rev 71, 57–85 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s41464-019-00066-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s41464-019-00066-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation