Skip to main content
Log in

Optimal Gerrymandering in a competitive environment

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Economic Theory Bulletin Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We analyze a model of optimal gerrymandering in which two parties simultaneously redistrict in a competition for influence in a legislature. Parties allocate geographic blocks to districts, in which the median voter determines the winner. The form of the optimal gerrymander involves “slices” of right-wing blocks paired with “slices” of left-wing blocks, as in Friedman and Holden (Am Econ Rev 98(1):113–144, 2008). We also show that, as one party controls the redistricting process in more states, that party designs districts such that the most extreme districts within its control become more extreme. We show that this comparative static holds for a broad class of objective functions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For a recount of the Obama campaign’s use of data, see for instance https://www.technologyreview.com/s/509026/how-obamas-team-used-big-data-to-rally-voters/.

  2. See, for instance https://www.theatlantic.com/politics/archive/2017/10/gerrymandering-technology-redmap-2020/543888/.

  3. See Friedman and Holden (2009) for a detailed breakdown.

  4. Note that all states require contiguity for districts. We do not model this constraint explicitly due to the significant added complexity required in such a model.

  5. One can model this reduced form “bliss point” approach as the implication of an assumption that voters have preferences over policy outcomes that satisfy “single-crossing” and that all candidates from a given party in a given state share a policy position. See Friedman and Holden (2008) for this treatment.

  6. The composition of this uncertainty will be elaborated upon in Sect. 3.

  7. It is trivial to extend these to include a third group of states redistricted exogenously to the model; this could represent bipartisan gerrymandering (in which no single party controls the organs of redistricting in a state) or court-mandated apportionment. For the sake of simplicity, we focus on the two-party case.

  8. This assumption matches the reality that 49 states must (by state law) redistrict within a window of about 6 months, after the release of the preliminary census but in time to organize the next Congressional elections. Furthermore, redistricting is typically a long and involved process, so that states cannot afford to wait for other states to complete their redistricting process.

  9. See footnote 11 of Friedman and Holden (2008) for a simple proof of this.

  10. See https://web.archive.org/web/20121217195343/http://fundrace.huffingtonpost.com/.

  11. For a more detailed discussion on this property, see Friedman and Holden (2008).

  12. An analogous discussion of this result is present in Friedman and Holden (2008).

  13. While this is mostly a technical assumption, in practice, both the Republican and Democratic parties control over 150 districts, and so this assumption is not unreasonable on its face. Furthermore, it seems natural for parties to spend considerably more time anticipating possible national shocks, such as a major recession or war, rather than the national influence of many uncorrelated local shocks.

  14. Total positivity has wide applications in economics. For instance, when K is a density \(TP_{2}\) is equivalent to the monotone likelihood ratio property.

  15. Of course, \(\Phi : {\mathbb {R}} \rightarrow \left[ 0,1\right] \) while our \(W:\left[ 0,1\right] \rightarrow {\mathbb {R}} \). But the domain restriction is unimportant.

  16. To see this, note that \( e^{-\log \left( \frac{1}{1+e^{-x}}\right) }=\frac{1}{1+e^{-x}},\) and that \( {-\log \left( \frac{1}{1+e^{-x}}\right) }\) is convex.

  17. The ballot initiatives were passed in Utah, Colorado and Georgia.

References

  • Bailey, D., Katz, J.: The impact of majority–minority districts in congressional elections. Cal Tech Working Paper (2005)

  • Besley, T., Preston, I.: Electoral Bias and Policy Choice. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 112(4), 1473–1510 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cameron, C., Epstein, D., O’Hallaran, S.: Do majority–minority districts maximize substantive black representation in congress? Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 90(4), 794–812 (1996)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coate, S., Knight, B.: Socially optimal districting: a theoretical and empirical exploration. Q. J. Econ. 122(4), 1409–1471 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, A.B., Holden, R.T.: Rethinking Racial and Partisan Gerrymandering. Univ. Chicago Law Rev. 78, 553–604 (2011)

    Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, D., O’Hallaran, S.: Measuring the impact of majority–minority voting districts. Am. J. Polit. Sci. 43(2), 367–395 (1999)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, J.N., Holden, R.T.: Optimal Gerrymandering: sometimes pack but never crack. Am. Econ. Rev. 98(1), 113–144 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, J.N., Holden, R.T.: The rising incumbent reelection rate: What’s Gerrymandering got to do with it? J. Polit. 71(2), 593–611 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilligan, T.W., Matsusaka, J.G.: Structural constraints on Partisan Bias under the efficient Gerrymander. Public Choice. 100(1/2), 65–84 (1999)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilligan, T.W., Matsusaka, J.G.: Public choice principles of redistricting. Public Choice. 129(3), 381–398 (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • Gimpel, J.G., Lee, F.E., Kaminski, J.: The political geography of campaign contributions in American politics. J. Polit. 68(3), 626–639 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gul, F., Pesendorfer, W.: Strategic redistricting. Am. Econ. Rev. 100(4), 1616–1641 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karlin, S.: Total positivity. Stanford Univ. Press Stanford CA 100(4), 1616–1641 (1968)

  • Owen, G., Grofman, B.: Optimal Partisan Gerrymandering. Econometrica 7(1), 5–22 (1988)

    Google Scholar 

  • Schoenberg, I.J.: On totally positive functions, laplace integrals and entire functions of the Laguerre-Polya-Schur type. Proc. Natl. Acad.Sci. 33, 11–17 (1947)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schoenberg, I.J.: On Polya frequency functions. Journal d’Analyse Mathématique. 1(1), 331–374 (1951)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shershtyuk, K.V.: How to Gerrymander: a formal analysis. Public Choice. 95, 27–49 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shotts, K.: How to Gerrymander: the effect of majority–minority mandates on Partisan Gerrymandering. Am. J. Polit. Sci. 45, 120–135 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shotts, K.: Gerrymandering, legislative composition, and national policy outcomes. Am. J. Polit. Sci. 46, 398–414 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Richard Holden.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Holden acknowledges ARC Future Fellowship FT130101159. We thank Christopher Teh for excellent research assistance.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1

This result follows the proof of Proposition 7 in Friedman and Holden (2008). Note that the objective function, for each district a party R must create, can be factored, such that

$$\begin{aligned} EW_{p}=B \left( \mu _{n,s}\right) K_{n,s}+\left( 1-B \left( \mu _{n,s}\right) \right) L_{n,s}, \end{aligned}$$

where \(K_{n,s}=E\left[ W_{p}|r_{n,s}=1\right] \) and \( L_{n,s}=E\left[ W_{p}|r_{n,s}=0\right] \) denote the expected value if party R were to win or lose district n in state s , respectively. Now, fix the districting plan (for both parties) and consider the change in the objective function resulting from a small deviation from the existing plan in district n with an offsetting change in district m, with both districts in state s . The derivative of the value function, with respect to this change (which, in shorthand, we denote \(\chi \)), is

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial E\left[ W_{p}\right] }{\partial \chi }=b \left( \mu _{n,s}\right) \left( K_{n,s}-L_{n,s}\right) \frac{\partial \mu _{n,s}}{\partial \chi }-b \left( \mu _{m,s}\right) \left( K_{m,s}-L_{m,s}\right) \frac{ \partial \mu _{m,s}}{\partial \chi }, \end{aligned}$$

which must equal 0 for the plan to be optimal. At this point, we note that, but for the constants \(K_{n,s}\), \(L_{n,s}\) , \(K_{m,s}\), and \(L_{m,s}\), this expression is identical to that in equation (7) of Friedman and Holden (2008). Thus, we can directly apply Lemmas 1 through 3 from that paper, which imply Proposition 1 in that paper, which is the result here. Since any optimal strategy must have this form, it must be that all equilibria are such that each party employs a strategy of this form. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 2

The proof follows exactly along the lines of Proposition 2 from Friedman and Holden (2008). Since all optimal districting schemes have this feature, it must be that all equilibria involve strategies with this feature. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 3

Using the definition of \(\phi ^{*}\), the maximization problem for party R can then be written as

$$\begin{aligned}&\max _{\left\{ \mu _{nR}\right\} }\int W^{\prime }\left( X\right) \left[ 1-Y\left( \phi ^{*}\left[ \left\{ \mu _{nR}\right\} ,\left\{ \mu _{nD}\right\} ;X\right] \right) \right] dX\text { \ } \\&\text {such that \ }\left\{ \mu _{nR}\right\} \in \Omega _{R}. \end{aligned}$$

In words, the party gets \(W^{\prime }\left( x\right) \) if the aggregate shock is higher than \(\phi ^{*}\left( X\right) \), and we must add up across all of the values X. At an optimum it cannot be the case that reallocating voters with positive mass between (say) district i to district j increases the value function and is still within the constraint set. However, consider such a reallocation and denote the increase in the median of district i of \(\Delta \mu _{i}\) and the decrease in the median of district j of \(\Delta \mu _{j}.\) Since the value function is differentiable it must be that for any two districts i and j in the same state

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\int W^{\prime }\left( X\right) y\left( \phi ^{*}\left( X\right) \right) \frac{\partial \phi ^{*}\left( X\right) }{\partial \mu _{i}}dX}{ \int W^{\prime }\left( X\right) y\left( \phi ^{*}\left( X\right) \right) \frac{\partial \phi ^{*}\left( X\right) }{\partial \mu _{j}}dX} =\lim _{\varepsilon \rightarrow 0}\frac{\Delta \mu _{j}}{\Delta _{\mu i}}, \end{aligned}$$

where the limit is taken such that the profile of switching voters is held constant. But, by our definition of \(\phi ^{*}\) above, we know that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \phi ^{*}}{\partial \mu _{i}}=\frac{c\left( \mu _{i}^{*}+\phi ^{*}\left( X\right) \right) }{\lambda \sum _{nR}c\left( \mu _{d}^{*}+\phi ^{*} \left( X\right) \right) +\left( 1-\lambda \right) \sum _{nD}c\left( \mu _{d}^{*}+\phi ^{*} \left( X\right) \right) }. \end{aligned}$$

Therefore the above ratio can be rewritten as

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\int W^{\prime }\left( X\right) y\left( \phi ^{*}\left[ \left\{ \mu _{nR}^{*}\right\} ,\left\{ \mu _{nD}^{*}\right\} ;X\right] \right) c\left( \mu _{i}+\phi ^{*}\left[ \left\{ \mu _{nR}^{*}\right\} ,\left\{ \mu _{nD}^{*}\right\} ;X\right] \right) dX}{\int W^{\prime }\left( X\right) y\left( \phi ^{*}\left[ \left\{ \mu _{nR}^{*}\right\} ,\left\{ \mu _{nD}^{*}\right\} ;X\right] \right) c\left( \mu _{j}+\phi ^{*}\left[ \left\{ \mu _{nR}^{*}\right\} ,\left\{ \mu _{nD}^{*}\right\} ;X\right] \right) dX}=\lim _{\varepsilon \rightarrow 0}\frac{\Delta \mu _{j}}{\Delta \mu _{i}}, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\phi ^{*}\) is that value associated with the equilibrium strategies. But these are the just the necessary conditions to the problem in which the gerrymanderer maximizes the alternative objective function

$$\begin{aligned}&\max _{\left\{ \mu _{nR}\right\} }\int W^{\prime }\left( X\right) y\left( \phi ^{*}\left[ \left\{ \mu _{nR}^{*}\right\} ,\left\{ \mu _{nD}^{*}\right\} ;X\right] \right) \sum C\left( \mu _{n,s}+\phi ^{*} \left[ \left\{ \mu _{nR}^{*}\right\} ,\left\{ \mu _{nD}^{*}\right\} ;X\right] \right) dX. \\&\text {such that }\left\{ \mu _{nR}\right\} \in \Omega _{R}. \end{aligned}$$

The proof for party D follows precisely the parallel logic. \(\square \)

Proof of Corollary 1

Consider the situation in which party R’s value function is

$$\begin{aligned} W_{n}= & {} \frac{x^{n}}{x^{n}+\left( 1-x\right) ^{n}} \\ W_{n}^{\prime }= & {} \frac{\left( \left( x-1\right) x\right) ^{n}\left( \log x-\log \left( 1-x\right) \right) }{\left( x^{n}+\left( 1-x\right) ^{n}\right) ^{2}} \end{aligned}$$

Note that, as \(n\rightarrow \infty , \)W limits to the desired function. By Proposition 3, party R solves the alternative maximization

$$\begin{aligned}&\max _{\left\{ \mu _{dR}\right\} }\int \left[ \frac{W_{n}^{\prime }\left( x\right) }{W_{n}^{\prime }\left( \frac{1}{2}\right) }y\left( \phi ^{*}\left( x\right) \right) \sum C\left( \mu _{n,s}+\phi ^{*}\left( \left\{ \mu _{dD}^{*}\right\} ,\left\{ \mu _{dR}^{*}\right\} ,x\right) \right) \right] dx \\&\text {such that }\left\{ \mu _{nR}\right\} \in \Omega _{R}. \end{aligned}$$

which is identical to equation (3) above but for scaling by the constant term \(W_{n}^{\prime }\left( \frac{1}{2}\right) \) . But as \(n\rightarrow \infty \), the weights

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{n\rightarrow \infty }\frac{W_{n}^{\prime }\left( x\right) }{ W_{n}^{\prime }\left( \frac{1}{2}\right) }\rightarrow \left\{ \begin{array}{cc} 0 &{} x\ne \frac{1}{2} \\ 1 &{} x=\frac{1}{2} \end{array} \right. . \end{aligned}$$

Thus the necessary conditions are simply that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{c\left( \mu _{i}+\phi ^{*}\right) }{c\left( \mu _{j}+\phi ^{*}\right) }=\frac{\Delta \mu _{j}}{\Delta \mu _{i}} \end{aligned}$$

These are the same necessary conditions as if party R simply maximized the number of seats won at critical value \(\phi ^{*}\left( \left\{ \mu _{nD}^{*}\right\} ,\left\{ \mu _{nR}^{*}\right\} ,\frac{1}{2}\right) \), which could be written

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{\left\{ \mu _{nR}\right\} }\sum _{nR}C\left( \mu _{n,s}+\phi ^{*}\left( \left\{ \mu _{nD}^{*}\right\} ,\left\{ \mu _{nR}^{*}\right\} ,\frac{1}{2}\right) \right) \\ \text {such that }\left\{ \mu _{nR}\right\} \in \Omega _{R}. \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 4

First consider a state redistricted by party R. Suppose \(N_s=2.\) Following Corollary 1, there are two FOCs that combine to imply

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{c\left( \mu _{1}+\phi ^{*}\right) }{c\left( \mu _{2}+\phi ^{*}\right) }=\frac{\Delta \mu _{2}}{\Delta \mu _{1}}. \end{aligned}$$

Writing \(\mu _{2}\left( \mu _{1}\right) \) one can substitute into the objective function above, so that the FOC becomes

$$\begin{aligned} \mu _{1}^{*}= & {} \arg \max _{\left\{ \mu _{1}\right\} }\left\{ C\left( \mu _{_{1}}+\phi ^{*} \right) +C\left( \mu _{2}\left( \mu _{_{1}}\right) +\phi ^{*} \right) \right\} \\\Rightarrow & {} \frac{c\left( \mu _{1}+\phi ^{*}\right) }{c\left( \mu _{2}+\phi ^{*}\right) }=-\frac{d\mu _{2}\left( \mu _{1}\right) }{\mathrm{d}\mu _{1}}. \end{aligned}$$

Of course, \(\frac{d\mu _{2}\left( \mu _{1}\right) }{d\mu _{1}}<0\). Then, by the implicit function theorem, we know that \(\frac{ \partial \mu _{1}^{*}}{\partial \phi ^{*}}<0\) if and only if the LHS is decreasing in \(\phi ^{*},\) which is true if and only if

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{c^{\prime }\left( \mu _{1}+\phi ^{*}\right) }{c^{\prime }\left( \mu _{2}+\phi ^{*}\right) }<\frac{c\left( \mu _{1}+\phi ^{*}\right) }{c\left( \mu _{2}+\phi ^{*}\right) } \end{aligned}$$

Note that by the equal mass constraint it must be that \(\frac{ \partial \mu _{2}}{\partial \phi ^{*}}\) is of the opposite sign as \(\frac{\partial \mu _{1}^{*}}{\partial \phi ^{*}}\). Moreover, \(\frac{\partial \mu _{1}^{*}}{\partial \phi ^{*}}\) depends entirely on whether the ratio \(\frac{c^{\prime }\left( \psi \right) }{c\left( \psi \right) }\) is increasing or decreasing in \( \psi .\) This ratio being decreasing is precisely the definition of log concavity and hence \(\frac{\partial \mu _{1}^{*}}{\partial \phi ^{*}}<0 . \)

To prove the result for \(N_{s} \ge 2,\) note that we maximize the objective function

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{\left\{ \mu _{nR}\right\} }\sum _{nR}C\left( \mu _{n}+\phi ^{*}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Consider a deviation in which one shifts \(\mu _{1}\) upwards by amount \(\Delta \mu _{1}\) and then shifts all other medians down by \(\Delta \mu _{-1}\). The no-benefit condition from such a deviation is

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{c\left( \mu _{1}+\phi ^{*}\right) }{\sum _{n\ne 1}c\left( \mu _{n}+\phi ^{*}\right) }=\frac{\Delta \mu _{-1}}{\Delta \mu _{1}}. \end{aligned}$$
(4)

Note, at this point, that the medians \(\left\{ \mu _{2},\ldots ,\mu _{N}\right\} \) are chosen optimally. Therefore, we can implicitly differentiate this expression to obtain the impact of \(\phi ^{*}\) on \(\mu _{1}\), since all deviations within the medians \( \left\{ \mu _{2},\ldots ,\mu _{N}\right\} \) have a second order impact on the value function, by the Envelope Theorem. From the \(N_{s}=2\) case we know that the ratio \(\frac{c\left( \mu _{1}+\phi ^{*}\right) }{c\left( \mu _{n}+\phi ^{*}\right) }\) is falling with \(\phi ^{*} , \) and therefore we know that the LHS of equation (4) is also decreasing in \(\phi ^{*}\) . Therefore, we know that \(\frac{\partial \mu _{1}^{*}}{\partial \phi ^{*}}<0 . \) A parallel argument establishes that \( \frac{\partial \mu _{N}^{*}}{\partial \phi ^{*}}>0 . \) The argument for states controlled by party D follows exactly the same logic. \(\square \)

Proof of Example 1

We can rewrite the expected number of seats won by party R as

$$\begin{aligned} X\left( \phi \right)= & {} k\int \left( \mu -\phi \right) \mathrm{d}M\left( \mu \right) \\= & {} k\left( \lambda {\overline{\mu }}_{R}+\left( 1-\lambda \right) {\overline{\mu }}_{D}+\phi \right) . \end{aligned}$$

and the expected value function for party R as

$$\begin{aligned} EW=\int W\left( k\left( \lambda {\overline{\mu }}_{R}+\left( 1-\lambda \right) \overline{ \mu }_{D}+\phi \right) \right) \mathrm{d}Y\left( \phi \right) . \end{aligned}$$

This equation shows that \({\overline{\mu }}_{R}\) is a sufficient statistic for the impact of party R districts on the aggregate outcome. Therefore each party does best simply to maximize the average of the median voters in the districts in their control. There is no strategic interaction at all between the parties in this special case. As a result, the share of districts \(\lambda \) under the control of party R can have no impact on the optimal gerrymander. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 5

Karlin (1968, p.30) shows that the convolution \(h=f\cdot g\) is \(PF_{n}\) if f and g are \(PF_{n}.\) By a theorem of Schoenberg (1947, (1951), \(PF_{2}\) of a density is equivalent to log-concavity. The assumption of uniformity of y means that we are left with the term \(\int W^{\prime }\left( x\right) c\left( \mu _{i}+\phi ^{*}\left( x\right) \right) \mathrm{d}x,\) which is \(PF_{2}\) since \(W^{\prime }\left( x\right) \) is \(PF_{2}\) and c is log-concave. Since \(W^{\prime }\left( x\right) \) is \(PF_{2}\) it is integrable and hence continuous. Now the proof of Proposition 4 applies. \(\square \)

Example 2

Suppose that the objective function takes on the form of the double-discontinuity function

$$\begin{aligned} W\left( X\right) =\left\{ \begin{array}{cc} 0 &{} X<\frac{1}{3} \\ \frac{1}{4} &{} X=\frac{1}{3} \\ \frac{1}{2} &{} \frac{1}{3}<X<\frac{2}{3} \\ \frac{3}{4} &{} X=\frac{2}{3} \\ 1 &{} X>\frac{2}{3} \end{array} \right. . \end{aligned}$$

Let \(N_{s}=2\), and \(\phi ^{*}\) be distributed uniformly for simplicity. Suppose that c is log-concave. By Proposition 3, we know that the ratio

$$\begin{aligned} DDR=\frac{c\left( \mu _{1}+\phi ^{*}\left( \frac{1}{3}\right) \right) +c\left( \mu _{1}+\phi ^{*}\left( \frac{2}{3}\right) \right) }{c\left( \mu _{2}+\phi ^{*}\left( \frac{1}{3}\right) \right) +c\left( \mu _{2}+\phi ^{*}\left( \frac{2}{3}\right) \right) } \end{aligned}$$
(5)

must be monotonic in \(\lambda \) for the comparative static to hold. By log-concavity, we know that the ratio \(\frac{c\left( \mu _{1}+\phi ^{*}\left( x\right) \right) }{c\left( \mu _{2}+\phi ^{*}\left( x\right) \right) }\) is increasing in \(\lambda \) for all x. But it will not generally be the case that the combined ratio in expression (5) is increasing. For instance, suppose that the following values hold for \( \lambda _{H}>\lambda _{L}.\)

 

\(\frac{c\left( \mu _{1}+\phi ^{*}\left( \frac{1}{3}\right) \right) }{ c\left( \mu _{2}+\phi ^{*}\left( \frac{1}{3}\right) \right) }\)

\(\frac{ c\left( \mu _{1}+\phi ^{*}\left( \frac{2}{3}\right) \right) }{c\left( \mu _{2}+\phi ^{*}\left( \frac{2}{3}\right) \right) }\)

DDR

\(\lambda _{H}\)

\(\frac{8}{2}\)

\(\frac{100}{100}\)

\(\frac{108}{102}\approx 1\)

\(\lambda _{L}\)

\(\frac{3}{1}\)

\(\frac{1}{2}\)

\(\frac{4}{3}>1.\)

Intuitively, it is important to note that the double-discontinuity objective function is an extreme example of a function that is not \(PF_{2},\) since it is the limit of an extremely bimodal function. When “convoluted” with \(W^{\prime },\)c loses its log-concavity, and so a fall in \(\phi ^{*}\) is no longer enough to guarantee an increase in the value of the higher median.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Friedman, J.N., Holden, R. Optimal Gerrymandering in a competitive environment. Econ Theory Bull 8, 347–367 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40505-020-00188-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40505-020-00188-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation