Skip to main content

Economy-wide effects of reducing the time spent for water fetching and firewood collection in Ethiopia

Abstract

Background

Water fetching and firewood collection are among home activities that are part of the daily routine of many households in rural Ethiopia. Households travel long distances and spend large amounts of time every day for collecting water and firewood. Fetching water and firewood reduce labor available for market related activities such as agriculture that affects production and productivity of these sectors negatively. Better access to water facility and energy efficient technology (such as improved stoves) is expected to release labor for market related activities that can have economy-wide impacts. The objective of this study is to investigate the economy-wide effects of access to water facility and improved stoves.

Methods

The study uses the updated 2004/05 Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) of Ethiopia. The SAM is modified to account for a detailed representation of water fetching, firewood collection and leisure activities and commodities. This study applies a single country Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) model to the updated SAM of Ethiopia. The simulation scenario is a 50% increase in the Total Factor Productivity (TFP) of both water fetching and firewood collection activities due to better access to water infrastructure and cooking improved stoves.

Results

The findings of the study show that better access to drinking water supply and improved stoves reduces labor time spent for water fetching and firewood collection. The released labor from water fetching and firewood collection partly reallocated to leisure consumption and partly to market related activities. Those freed labors that are reallocated to marketed sectors including agricultural and non-agricultural activities leads to increase employment and enhance domestic production. Better access to drinking water and improved stoves also enhances household welfare. Households that allocate a relatively large proportion of labor to water fetching and firewood collection gain relatively more welfare. Macroeconomic indicators such as GDP, total domestic production, absorption, and imports are also positively affected due to improved access to water and energy efficient technology.

Conclusions

It is helpful to recognize the economic significance of labor released from water fetching and firewood collection in any developing economy with a limited supply of water facility and access to energy technology.

Background

Access to drinking water and household energy are among the development challenges of developing countries. Approximately, 663 million people around the world lack access to improved drinking water; out of this, 50% live in Sub-Saharan Africa. The target of the United Nation Millennium Development Goal (UNMDG) to reduce the proportion of population without sustainable access to drinking water by half between 1990 and 2015 was unachievable by most of Sub-Saharan Africa countries but there are some on-going positive changes. However, Ethiopia is among one of the countries that successfully achieved this target. During 1990 only 13% of the Ethiopian population had access to improved water but in 2015 half of the population is able to get improved water sources (WHO and UNICEF 2015).

However, the majority of Ethiopian households are currently unable to access drinking water close to their neighbourhood. Only 12% of the Ethiopian population has access to piped water (WHO and UNICEF 2015). The main sources of drinking water for Ethiopian households include public standpipe, protected/unprotected dug well/spring, ponds, lakes and rivers (WHO and UNICEF 2010). These sources of water are usually located far from the neighbourhood of the household. The majority of Ethiopian households often spend several hours per day for collecting drinking water from remote sources. For instance, 16% of urban and 34% of rural household on average travel between 1 and 2 h per trip for water fetching. In rural areas of Ethiopia, household spent a longer hours for fetching water. For example, 10% of rural household on average travel more than 2 h per trip for collecting water (Fig. 1).

Fig. 1
figure 1

Source: Author’s compilation based on Central Statistical Agency (2014)

Classification of Ethiopian households by water fetching time per round trip

Ethiopia is also a country where the majority of the population has limited access to electricity. More than 75% of Ethiopians live without access to electricity. Nearly all rural households and 80% of urban households in Ethiopia depend on biomass fuel for cooking (International Energy Agency 2014). Biomass fuel is sourced from firewood, animal dung, and crop residue. The majority of households use a traditional cooking stove which is less energy efficient (Rehfuess et al. 2006). Furthermore, due to underdeveloped road infrastructure and deforestation, households travel long distances and spent several hours for collecting firewood. For example, 22% and 36% of urban and rural households spent more than 2 h per trip to collect firewood respectively (Fig. 2).

Fig. 2
figure 2

Source: Author’s compilation based on Central Statistical Agency (2014)

Classification of Ethiopian households by firewood collection time per round trip

Therefore, Ethiopian households allocate significant quantity of labor for water fetching and firewood collection activities. Furthermore, water fetchers and firewood collectors are usually agricultural laborers in Ethiopia. Specifically, fetching water and firewood reduces labor time available for marketed sectors including non-agricultural activities that adversely affects production and productivity of these sectors. The time spent for fetching water and firewood can be significantly reduced through improved access to water infrastructure, and household energy saving technology (for example, improved stoves). The freed labor from water and firewood collection can be partly reallocated to marketed activities or partly reallocated to leisure. Labor reallocated to market related activities would have tremendous economy-wide implications.

Previous studies incorporate aggregate home activities including care of children and the elderly, cooking, cleaning, fetching water and collecting firewood in the CGE model such as Fontana and Wood (2000). Little or no attempts were made to distinguish between the varieties of home activities. Different types of home activities satisfy different objectives and are accomplished by different technologies. Therefore, the innovation of this study is separately depicting labor-intensive home activities such as water fetching and firewood collection and leisure into the economy wide model. The objective of this study is to investigate the economy-wide effects of better access to water facility and improved stoves.

Materials and methods

Data

This study uses the updated 2004/05 Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) of Ethiopia (Mosa 2018). The original 2005/06 SAM of Ethiopia was built by Ethiopian Development Research Institute (EDRI) in cooperation with the University of Sussex (Tebekew et al. 2009). Mosa (2018) updated the 2004/05 SAM of Ethiopia with a detailed representation of water fetching, firewood collection and leisure activities and commodities. Since water fetching and firewood collection are performed by households, distinct water fetching and firewood collection activities are added to the updated SAM in accordance with household classification. Following the approach developed by Fontana and Wood (2000) a separate activity and commodity accounts are created for leisure. Since households consume leisure, leisure activities are added to the SAM in accordance with household classification. Furthermore, distinct commodity accounts are also created for water fetching, firewood collection and leisure. Transactions for water fetching, firewood collection and leisure in the SAM are computed based on the value of labor time allocated to these activities. The values of labor time spend for water fetching, firewood collection and leisure activities are computed based on the shadow wage of labor.

The updated micro-SAM has 199 activities and 95 commodities, 34 representative household groups that are categorized by agro-ecological zones, poverty status and source of non-agricultural income, 10 labor categories that are classified by gender and occupations and 21 other factors of production such as capital and land that are differentiated by agro-ecological zones. The SAM also has 17 tax accounts and other core accounts such as government, investment and the rest of the world. The updated SAM comprises 481 row and column accounts. The updated balanced macro SAM of Ethiopia is depicted in Table 1. Furthermore, the detail micro SAM accounts is provided in Appendix 1.

Table 1 Macro SAM of Ethiopia (in billions Ethiopian birr)

Model

This study applies Static General Equilibrium (STAGE) model (McDonald 2007) to the updated SAM of Ethiopia (Mosa 2018) STAGE is a single country CGE model. It is a Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) based CGE model that has linear and non-linear relationships that govern the behavior of agents in the model. Households choose a bundle of commodities to consume in order to maximize Stone-Geary utility function. The commodities consumed by households are a composite of imported and locally produced commodities. The constant elasticity of substitution (CES) is used to combine imported and locally produced commodities by assuming that these commodities are imperfect substitutes using the Armington assumption (Armington 1969).

Several types of model specific elasticities are used in the calibration of the CGE model applied for this study. Elasticities in the model include commodity, activity and income elasticities. Commodity elasticities involve Armington’s substitution elasticities between imported and domestically produced commodities and the elasticities of transformation between local commodities and export commodities. The commodity elasticities also include export demand elasticities and substitution elasticities for aggregation of commodity output. Activity elasticities cover elasticities of substitution between intermediate inputs and value added input and the substitution between different primary factors such as labor, capital and land in the nested production function. Income elasticities are elasticities for the consumption of different commodities by households. In this study, commodity, activity and Frisch elasticities are adopted from Flaig (2014). On the other hand, most of the income elasticities are adapted from Tafere et al. (2010).

Policy simulations

Simulation scenarios

The construction of drinking water infrastructure around the vicinity of households and providing access to energy technology (such as improved cooking stoves) potentially reduce the time spent on water fetching and firewood collection. This would improve the efficiency of collecting water and firewood as less labor would be required to collect the same amount of water and firewood. Therefore, this study analyses the scenario of an increase in the Total Factor Productivity (TFP) of water fetching and firewood collection activities due to improved access to drinking water and energy technology.

The quantity of labor time freed in response to better access to drinking water supply depends on agro-ecological zone and place of residence (rural vs. urban). This complicates the estimation of the exact amount of time saved because of improved access to drinking water infrastructure. However, the value of time saved from water fetching can be approximated in a certain range of intervals. For instance, Cook et al. (2013) in Oromia region of Ethiopia reported that improved access to water supply can successfully reduce water fetching time by 35% to over 90% per day. Accordingly, in this study, it is assumed that improved access to drinking water supply can reduce the time spent for fetching water on average by 50%.

Similarly, the amount of time saved due to improved access to household energy relies on access to modern cooking technology and availability of traditional source of energy. Empirical evidence by Gaia Consulting Oy and Ethio Resource Group (2012) in Ethiopia indicates that access to improved stove reduces household’s fuel consumption by more than 50%. This led to approximately 50% less firewood collection time. Accordingly, in this study, it is also assumed that in response to improved access to household energy saving services (for example, improved stove), efficiency of firewood collection activities can be increased on average by 50%.

Therefore, the simulation scenario is 50% increase in the TFP of both water fetching and firewood collection activities in response to improved access to water and household energy saving technology.

The cost of financing water and energy infrastructure are obtained from domestic sources or international donors (loans and grants). Specifically, the main sources of financing water and energy infrastructure in Ethiopia are government treasury, user contributions and support from international donors. Indeed, approximately three-fourth of the total national water supply budget is sourced from the treasury of government and the remaining share is covered by international donors and user contribution (World Bank 2016).

In the policy scenario, the funds for constructing drinking water and energy facilities are sourced from government savings and foreign savings (loans and grants). In other words, in order to finance the construction of water infrastructure and energy efficient technology, government savings and foreign savings are exogenously increased in the model. Since government treasury is the largest source of funds in the national water supply budget, the larger share of funds is obtained from the government savings relative to foreign savings. The total government savings are 5.4 billion birr and foreign savings are 10.9 billion birr in the updated SAM.

For approximating the effect of government expenditure on reducing water fetching and firewood collection time, expert opinions and estimates of the budget required for achieving universal water access as defined by the UNMDG are used in this study. According to experts’ opinion, 0.5 to 1.5 h per day per household from water fetching can be saved in Sub-Saharan African countries by achieving universal access to water i.e. a 50% reduction in the share of population that is unable to secure improved drinking water (World Health Organization 2012). Therefore, for this study it is assumed that if Ethiopia achieved universal water access, the average water fetching time will be reduced by 50%.

According to World Bank (2016), the aggregate budget required for achieving universal access to water in Ethiopia is 16.7 billion birr. The country already spent 13.6 billion birr in the year 2012. Therefore, it is assumed that an extra 3.1 (16.7–13.6) billion birr investment is needed for achieving universal water access (World Bank 2016). It is also assumed that the required fund (3.1 billion) is generated through a 37% increase in government savings (i.e. 2 billion birr) and a 10% increase in foreign savings (i.e. 1.1 billion birr). Therefore, for financing water and energy infrastructure, government savings exogenously increase by 37% and foreign savings increase by 10%. Since the government and foreign savings are not channelled to investments, the multiplier effects are not accounted for in this simulation.

Model closure rule

The exchange rate is flexible while the external balance is fixed in the model. The exchange rate is flexible to produce the fixed level of foreign savings for funding water infrastructure and energy efficient technology. Investment driven savings is chosen where investment is fixed and savings are flexible in the model such that savings adjust for the saving-investment balance. Alternatively, savings driven investment closure can be chosen where savings are fixed but investment is flexible to adjust the saving-investment balance to generate the required level of funds for the construction of water and energy infrastructure.

Government raises funds through income tax replacement. Government savings are fixed and income tax rates are endogenously adjusted to produce a fixed level of government savings for financing the construction of water infrastructure and energy efficient technology. Alternatively, government investment (expenditure) is fixed and income tax rates are endogenously adjusted to produce a fixed level of public expenditure for financing water and energy infrastructure. The consumer price index (CPI) is chosen as a numeraire. Furthermore, factor supplies are fixed in the model and in order to enable the mobility of water fetcher and firewood collectors across different sectors, perfect factor mobility is assumed in the model.

Results and discussion

The study examines the impact on labor reallocation across sectors, domestic production, domestic price and household consumption, household’s welfare and implication on major macroeconomic indicators.

Effect on labor reallocation

In rural Ethiopia, water fetching and firewood collection is commonly accomplished by reducing the daily agricultural labor time. On the other hand, in urban parts of the country, unskilled workers commonly collect water and firewood. Water fetching and firewood collection are labor-intensive household activities. An improved TFP of water fetching and firewood collection results in reduction of labor required to perform these activities. Table 2 describes the change in labor demand across sectors in response to improved TFP of water fetching and firewood collection activities.

Table 2 Simulated changes (percentage) in labor demand across sectors

The simulation result indicates that because of a 50% rise in TFP, labor demand declines on average (weighted) by 22.3% for firewood collection and by 21.7% for water fetching activities. Because of better access to water facility, households consume additional water and relatively more labor is required to fetch the extra drinking water. Therefore, the labor demand for water fetching does not decline by the full 50%. On the other hand, employment of labor in agriculture, industry, and service activities increases on average by 1.6%, 0.9% and 0.5% respectively because of absorbing the released labor from water fetching and firewood collection. The agricultural sector absorbs a larger percentage of labor relative to industry and service sectors. This happens because large shares of water fetchers and firewood collectors are agricultural laborers in Ethiopia. Thus, when water fetching and firewood collection activities are effectively accomplished, agriculture absorbs a relatively larger proportion of freed laborers relative to other sectors (such as industry and service). Furthermore, most of the freed laborers prefer to enjoy extra leisure and hence labor is reallocated to leisure (4.6%).

Effect on domestic production

Table 3 depicts the change (weighted) in domestic production because of increased TFP of water fetching and firewood collection activities. Production of water fetching on average increases by 17.5% and firewood collection on average increases by 16.5% due to enhanced TFP. Furthermore, labor released from water fetching and firewood collection is transferred into other sectors and stimulates agricultural and non-agricultural (such as industry and services) production in the destination sector. Production of agriculture, industry and services on average increases by 1.2%, 0.6% and 0.4%, respectively, due to employment of extra labor which is attracted from water fetching and firewood collection. Production in the agricultural sector increases by a higher proportion relative to other sectors (industry and services).

Table 3 Simulated changes (percentage) in domestic production by sectors

Higher TFP in water fetching and firewood collection activities provides larger proportions of released labor for agriculture relative to industry or services and hence production in this sector increases more. Furthermore, the production of leisure increases by 4.6%, which is relatively greater than other sectors such as agriculture, industry, and services. This happens because there was less or no time left for leisure activities when household collects water and firewood from the distant sources and therefore, the freed labor prefers to enjoy leisure and hence more labors are reallocated to leisure. Additionally, the larger production of leisure can be explained by the fact that the consumption of leisure is more sensitive to the income changes relative to other commodities. Therefore, an increase in household income (due to reallocation of labor to income generating activities) raises the demand for leisure that leads to a more production of leisure.

Effect on domestic price and household consumption

In response to higher TFP in water fetching and firewood collection activities, a large amount of labor is released and reallocated to other activities. The labor reallocated to other sectors enhances domestic production (Table 3) and at the same time results in higher income for households through increased factor payments. The simultaneous rise in both domestic production and household income differently affects domestic prices and household consumption. Conceptually, increased domestic production results in higher commodity supply in the market and this can potentially reduce domestic supply prices of commodities (PQS) and purchaser prices (PQD). On the other hand, the freed labor from fetching water and firewood and subsequently reallocated to marketed sectors brings extra income to the households which increases household consumption demand (QCD). This potentially increases domestic prices.

Table 4 describes the percentage change (weighted) in domestic prices and household demand in response to higher TFP in water fetching and firewood collection. The simulation results indicate that because of higher TFP in water fetching and firewood collection, QCD increases for all commodities: agricultural by 1.7%, industrial by 1.3%, services by 0.6%, water fetching by 17.5%, firewood collection by 16.5% and leisure by 4.6%. Domestic prices for agricultural, industrial, and service commodities on average increase by 2.1% and for leisure commodities on average increase by 2.3%. This implies that the effect of increasing income dominates the price effect. The extra income results in upward shift in households’ consumption demand and hence increases domestic prices.

Table 4 Simulated changes (percentage) in domestic price and household demand

On the other hand, household demand for water fetching and firewood collection commodities increases but domestic prices for these commodities decrease on average by 32.2% and 32.1%, respectively. Household demand for water fetching and firewood collection increases by 17.5% and 16.5% respectively. This can be explained by the fact that because of efficiency gains in water fetching and firewood collection, large quantities of water and firewood are produced and supplied to the market. Water and firewood become relatively cheaper and hence consumption demand for these commodities increases (due to income and substitution effects).

Effect on household welfare

Increased TFP of water fetching and firewood collection also affects household welfare. Figure 3 shows the equivalent variation (EV) in percent of base income to examine the actual welfare changes across household groups. Welfare improvement happens to all groups of rural households but the amount of welfare gains varies among households. Different household groups allocate divergent quantities of labor for water fetching and firewood collection. Accordingly, welfare gains depend on household endowment of labor that can be potentially allocated to water fetching and firewood collection. In other words, households that allocate a relatively larger proportion of labor to water fetching and firewood collection obtain high welfare gains. For instance, non-poor and poor rural households in agro-ecology zones 1 and 5 allocate the highest proportion of labor to water fetching and firewood collection relative to other groups of households. Because of increase in the TFP of water fetching and firewood collection, welfare gains by these household groups are higher than to other household groups.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Source: Author’s computation based on model results

Simulated changes (percentage) in household welfare (EV/base income)

On the other hand, the divergent share of water and energy consumption expenditure also results in different welfare gains across household groups. The share of consumption expenditure to water and energy commodities differs by household groups. Better access to water and energy infrastructure increases the supply of water and energy and these commodities become relatively cheaper. Households that spend a larger share of their consumption expenditure on water and energy commodities gain more welfare relative to others. For example, poor rural households located in agro-ecology zones 1 and 5 spend a larger proportion of consumption expenditure on water and energy commodities. Because of better access to water and energy facility, the welfare gains to these household groups are higher than to other household groups.

Similarly, the welfare of poor urban households is also positively affected by increasing TFP of water fetching and firewood collection. Since urban households allocate less labor for collecting water and firewood, their welfare gain is lesser than for rural households. However, the welfare of urban non-poor households is negatively affected. This can be explained by the fact that some portions of financing the construction of water and energy facility are obtained from government savings that are raised through income tax. Since urban non-poor households contribute, a larger share of tax to the government, their consumption expenditure decreases and hence welfare declines.

Macroeconomic effects

Reallocation of released labor from water fetching and firewood collection to other sectors creates economy-wide linkages and positively affects the macroeconomic indicators such as gross domestic product (GDP), total domestic production, absorption, import, export and exchange rate.

Figure 4 depicts the macroeconomic effect of higher TFP in water fetching and firewood collection. Total domestic production increases by 2%, GDP by 2.6%, absorption by 2.8%, imports by 1.5% and the exchange rate by 1.3%. The released labor from water fetching and firewood collection is reallocated to productive sectors that accelerate domestic production. This leads to an increase in domestic consumption (absorption) and import. Furthermore, reallocated labor promotes the growth of the economy and hence the GDP increases.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Source: Author’s computation based on model results

Macroeconomic impact (percentage changes)

Sensitivity analysis

The sensitivity of model results due to the change in the core model parameters such as the income elasticity of leisure is discussed in this section. Specifically, this section discusses the sensitivity of labor demand, domestic production, household welfare, and major macroeconomic effects due to the change in the income elasticity of leisure. Sensitivity analysis is carried out by changing the income elasticity of leisure from 2 to 3 (50% increase) and 4 (100% increase). The sensitivity of model results in response to the change in income elasticity of leisure is provided in Appendix 2. The percentage change in labor demand and domestic production varies when the income elasticity of leisure increases from 2 to 3 and 4. When the income elasticity of leisure is higher, a larger share of the freed labor gets into leisure and a smaller proportion is reallocated to other sectors (agriculture, industry and services) (see Appendix 2.1 for details).

Household welfare is not very sensitive to the change in the income elasticity of leisure. All groups of households except urban non-poor households have less welfare gains when the income elasticity of leisure increases from 2 to 3 and 4 (see Appendix 2.2 for the details). The reason is that leisure does not create multiplier effects through commodity demand. The macroeconomic indicators such as absorption, import demand, GDP from expenditure and total domestic production also slightly vary due to the change in the income elasticity of leisure. Specifically, absorption, import demand, GDP, and total domestic production increase by a lesser percentage when the income elasticity of leisure is higher (see Appendix 2.3 for the details).

Therefore, the change in the income elasticity of leisure leads to some changes in labor demand, domestic production, household welfare, and major macroeconomic indicators. Although the changes in the income elasticity of leisure result in slight disparities in the magnitude of simulation outcome, the direction of changes remains the same as well as the order of size.

Comparison of results with previous studies

The expansion of improved drinking water infrastructure has both costs and economic benefits. Some of the costs include investment cost (for example, cost associated with the initial construction of the water facility) and recurrent cost (for example, maintenance cost). The benefits of improved access to drinking water supply include health related benefits (for example, reduction of waterborne diseases, less mortality, avoidance of the loss of productive time due to diseases and saved health care expenditure) and the opportunity cost of travel and waiting time saved from fetching water.

The World Health Organization (WHO) estimates the benefit–cost–ratio (BCR) of universal access to improved drinking water for 136 low and middle-income countries in 2012 (World Health Organization 2012). These countries are grouped into nine sub-regions: South-Eastern Asia (S.E.Asia), Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA), Latin America and Caribbean (LAC), Southern Asia (S.Asia), Eastern Asia (E.Asia), North Africa (N.Africa), Western Asia (W.Asia), Caucasus and Central Asia (CCA) and Oceania. The BCR was estimated for individual countries initially and then it was aggregated to a region weighted by the respective country’s population.

According to the WHO’s study, the benefits of universal access to drinking water outweigh the costs for most of the countries (Fig. 5). Figure 5 depicts the BCR of universal access to improved drinking water across countries ranging from 0.6 in Oceania to 3.7 in S.Asia. Each additional dollar of investment provided for improved drinking water results in 0.6 to 3.7 dollar worth of benefits. The bigger proportions of these benefits are derived from the opportunity cost of labour time saved due to improved access to water supply.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Source: Author’s compilation based on World Health Organization (2012)

BCR of improved access to water supply (US$ return per US$ invested)

On the other hand, improved access to household energy (for example, improved cooking stove) has costs and economic benefits. The costs include the purchase of stoves and installation cost among others. On the other hand, the benefits include health related benefits (reduction of diseases caused by IAP), less expenditure on health care services linked to IAP, productivity gain due to better health, time saved from cooking and fuel collection, environmental benefits (for example, fewer trees cut down). Figure 6 shows the BCR of reducing the share of the population without access to improved cooking stove by 50% across WHO sub-regions. The WHO regions are South-East Asia Region (SEAR), Western Pacific Region (WPR), Eastern Mediterranean Region (EMR), and Region of the Americas (AMR), African Region (AFR) and European Region (EUR).

Fig. 6
figure 6

Source: Author’s compilation based on Hutton et al. (2006)

BCR of access to improved stove (US$ return per US$ invested)

The estimated BCR of access to improved cooking stove varies across different sub-regions; it ranges from 37.4 to 137.4 in AFR and WPR respectively. Each additional dollar of investments to provide improved stoves results in 37.4 to 137.4 worth of US dollar benefits. The largest share of benefits is derived from the saved time that would have been used for cooking and collecting firewood (Hutton et al. 2006).

Because of the difference in the methodologies used and in the context of case study area, it is not easy to compare the result of this study with the previous studies. Although the methodology applied and the case study areas in the previous studies mentioned above are varied, this study is in consistent with the findings of the previous studies that confirm the cost of providing water facility and improved stoves outweighs the benefits gained.

Conclusions

The findings of this study show that better access to water facility and improved stoves reduces the labor time spent for water fetching and firewood collection. Those freed labor are reallocated to agricultural, non-agricultural activities and/or leisure. This lead to increase employment in all sectors, and enhances domestic production. Households also enjoy extra leisure because of better access to water and energy infrastructure and overall welfare improved. Furthermore, the released labor facilitates aggregate domestic production, consumption and imports and hence growth of the economy. Although the simulation results are sensitive to the change in the income elasticity of leisure, the direction and order of magnitude of results are unaltered in all scenarios.

Improved access to drinking water and improved stoves has health and non-health related benefits such as reduction of waterborne diseases and indoor air pollution, saved health care expenditure, productivity gain due to better health and the time saved from water fetching and firewood collection. However, this study analyzes only the benefits of freed labor from water fetching and firewood collection due to improved access to water infrastructure and improved stoves. Therefore, the economic gains of better access to water and improved stoves are only partially captured by this study.

This study used static model. A similar future work can apply dynamic model for analyzing the time path of benefits derived from investment in water supply and improved stoves. Furthermore, the precision of behavioral parameters such as elasticities in the model can be improved by estimating the value of these elasticities using econometrics.

Availability of data and materials

Some of the data used for this study can be accessed from Ethiopian Development Research Institute. Other support data can be obtained from the corresponding author up on request.

Abbreviations

CGE:

Computable General Equilibrium

CPI:

Consumer price index

GDP:

Gross domestic product

EV:

Equivalent variation

EDRI:

Ethiopian Development Research Institute

Eyleisure:

Income elasticity of leisure

IEA:

International Energy Agency

PQS:

Domestic supply prices

PQD:

Domestic purchaser prices

QCD:

Household consumption demand

STAGE:

Static General Equilibrium Model

SAM:

Social Accounting Matrix

TFP:

Total Factor Productivity

UNMDG:

United Nation Millennium Development Goal

WHO:

World Health Organization

UNICEF:

United Nation International Children’s Fund

OECD:

Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development

References

  • Armington PS (1969) A theory of demand for products distinguished by place of production. IMF Staff Papers 16(1):159–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Central Statistical Agency (2014) Ethiopia Time Use Survey 2013: Main Report. Addis Ababa

  • Cook J, Masuda Y, Fortmann L, Gugety MK, Smith-Nilson M (2013) How Does Improving Access to Rural Water Supply Change Household Time Use in Ethiopia? Draft January 2013. Seattle

  • Flaig D (2014) Factor Mobility and Heterogeneous Labor in Computable General Equilibrium Modeling Dissertation Submitted in Fulfilment of the Requirements for the Degree ‘Doktor der Agrarwissenschaften.’ Universität Hohenheim

  • Fontana M, Wood A (2000) Modeling the Effects of Trade on Women, at Work and at Home. World Dev 28(7):1173–1190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaia Consulting Oy, Ethio Resource Group (2012) Improved Cook Stoves: Final Report, GHG Mitigation and Sustainable Development Through the Promotion of Energy Efficient Cooking in Social Instituitions in Ethiopia. Helsinki

  • Hutton G, Rehfuess E, Tediosi F, Weiss S (2006) Evaluation of the costs and benefits of household energy and health interventions at global and regional levels. WHO, Geneva

    Google Scholar 

  • International Energy Agency (2014) Africa Energy Outlook: A Focus on Energy Prospects in Sub-Saharan Africa. World Energy Outlook Special Report, Paris

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • McDonald S (2007) A Static Applied General Equilibrium Model: Technical Documentation STAGE Version 1: July 2007 Draft. Oxford

  • Mosa A (2018) Non-agricultural activities and household time use in Ethiopia: a computable general equilibrium model analysis. PhD Dissertation. University of Hohenheim, Stuttgart

    Google Scholar 

  • Rehfuess E, Mehta S, Prüss-Ãœstün A (2006) Assessing household solid fuel use: multiple implications for the millennium development goals. Environ Health Perspect 114(3):373–378

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tafere K, Taffesse AS, Tamru S (2010) Food Demand Elasticities in Ethiopia: Estimates Using Household Income Consumption Expenditure (HICE) Survey Data (No. 011). Addis Ababa

  • Tebekew T, Amoge A, Teferra B, Seyoum Z, Amha M, Beyene H, Fisseha E, Tsehaye E, Ahmed H, Robinson S, Willenbockel D, Dorosh P, McDonald S (2009) Ethiopia Input Output Table and Social Accounting Matrix. Addis Ababa

  • WHO, UNICEF (2010) Rapid assessment of drinking-water quality in the federal democratic republic of Ethiopia: country report of the pilot project implementation in 2004–2005. WHO, UNICEF, Geneva

    Google Scholar 

  • WHO, UNICEF (2015) Progress on sanitation and drinking water: 2015 update and MDG assessment. WHO, Geneva

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2016) Ethiopia public expenditure review. World Bank, Washington

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • World Health Organization (2012) Global costs and benefits of drinking water supply and sanitation interventions to reach the MDG target and universal coverage (No. 12. 01). World Health Organization, Geneva

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to Ethiopian Development Research Institute for allowing us to access the Social Accounting Matrix of Ethiopia.

Funding

Not applicable.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

This paper is part of the corresponding author’s Ph.D. dissertation. The rest authors were supervisor (HG) and co-supervisor (KS) to the corresponding author. Therefore, the corresponding author was the major contributor, the co-author contributed through discussion, reading and approving the final manuscript. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Abdulaziz Mosa.

Ethics declarations

Ethics approval and consent to participate

Not applicable.

Consent for publication

Not applicable.

Competing interests

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Structure of the updated 2005/06 SAM of Ethiopia

1.1 Activity accounts

1.1.1 Agricultural activities

Abbreviations

Descriptions

atef1

Growing teff in zone 1

atef2

Growing teff in zone 2

atef3

Growing teff in zone 3

atef4

Growing teff in zone 4

atef5

Growing teff in zone 5

abar1

Growing barley in zone 1

abar2

Growing barley in zone 2

abar3

Growing barley in zone 3

abar4

Growing barley in zone 4

abar5

Growing barley in zone 5

awhea1

Growing wheat in zone 1

awhea2

Growing wheat in zone 2

awhea3

Growing wheat in zone 3

awhea4

Growing wheat in zone 4

awhea5

Growing wheat in zone 5

amaiz1

Growing maize in zone 1

amaiz2

Growing maize in zone 2

amaiz3

Growing maize in zone 3

amaiz4

Growing maize in zone 4

amaiz5

Growing maize in zone 5

asorg1

Growing sorghum in zone 1

asorg2

Growing sorghum in zone 2

asorg3

Growing sorghum in zone 3

asorg4

Growing sorghum in zone 4

asorg5

Growing sorghum in zone 5

apul1

Growing pulses in zone 1

apul2

Growing pulses in zone 2

apul3

Growing pulses in zone 3

apul4

Growing pulses in zone 4

apul5

Growing pulses in zone 5

avegfr1

Growing vegetable and nec in zone 1

avegfr2

Growing vegetable and nec in zone 2

avegfr3

Growing vegetable and nec in zone 3

avegfr4

Growing vegetable and nec in zone 4

avegfr5

Growing vegetable and nec in zone 5

aoils1

Growing oil seeds in zone 1

aoils2

Growing oil seeds in zone 2

aoils3

Growing oil seeds in zone 3

aoils4

Growing oil seeds in zone 4

aoils5

Growing oil seeds in zone 5

acash1

Growing cash crops nec in zone 1

acash2

Growing cash crops nec in zone 2

acash3

Growing cash crops nec in zone 3

acash4

Growing cash crops nec in zone 4

acash5

Growing cash crops nec in zone 5

aenset1

Growing enset in zone 1

aenset2

Growing enset in zone 2

aenset3

Growing enset in zone 3

aenset4

Growing enset in zone 4

aenset5

Growing enset in zone 5

acrop1

Growing crop nec in zone 1

acrop2

Growing crop nec in zone 2

acrop3

Growing crop nec in zone 3

acrop4

Growing crop nec in zone 4

acrop5

Growing crop nec in zone 5

acoff1

Growing coffee in zone 1

acoff2

Growing coffee in zone 2

acoff3

Growing coffee in zone 3

acoff4

Growing coffee in zone 4

alivst1

Livestock farming in zone 1

alivst2

Livestock farming in zone 2

alivst3

Livestock farming in zone 3

alivst4

Livestock farming in zone 4

alivst5

Livestock farming in zone 5

afisfor

Forestry and fishing

1.1.2 Industrial activities

Abbreviations

Descriptions

amining

Mining

aofood

Production, processing of food and related products

adairy

Manufacturing of dairy products

agmill

Manufacturing of grain mill products

agmillserv

Manufacturing of grain mill services

asug

Manufacture of sugar

abev

Manufacturing of beverage products

amtob

Manufacturing of tobacco products

atext

Manufacturing of textile products

aapar

Manufacturing of wearing apparels

aleath

Manufacturing of leather products

awood

Manufacturing of wood and products of wood

apaperp

Manufacture of paper and paper products

achem

Chemicals products manufacturing

aminprod

Mineral products manufacturing

abmetalp

Manufacturing metal products

amach

Machinery manufacturing

aelecq

Electronic equipments manufacturing

aveh

Motor vehicles manufacturing

aomanu

Furniture and related products manufacturing

1.1.3 Service activities

Abbreviations

Descriptions

aelect

Electricity

awater

Collection purification and distribution of water

acons

Service of construction

atrad

Trade

ahotel

Hotel

atrncom

Transport, communication and storage

afserv

Financial intermediation

arest

Real estate, business activities and renting

apadmin

Public administration

aeduc

Education

aheal

Health

aoserv

Business activities and related social services

1.1.4 Water fetching activities

Abbreviations

Descriptions

awfHH-Rural_EZ1Pagr

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ1Pagr

awfHH-Rural_EZ1Pmix

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ1Pmix

awfHH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr

awfHH-Rural_EZ2Pagr

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ2Pagr

awfHH-Rural_EZ2Pmix

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ2Pmix

awfHH-Rural_EZ2nagr

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ2nagr

awfHH-Rural_EZ3Pagr

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ3Pagr

awfHH-Rural_EZ3Pmix

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ3Pmix

awfHH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr

awfHH-Rural_EZ4Pagr

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ4PPagr

awfHH-Rural_EZ4Pmix

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ4Pmix

awfHH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr

awfHH-Rural_EZ5Pagr

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ5Pagr

awfHH-Rural_EZ5Pmix

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ5Pmix

awfHH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr

awfHH-Rural_EZ1NPagr

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ1NPagr

awfHH-Rural_EZ1NPmix

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ1NPmix

awfHH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr

awfHH-Rural_EZ2NPagr

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ2NPagr

awfHH-Rural_EZ2NPmix

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ2NPmix

awfHH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr

awfHH-Rural_EZ3NPagr

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ3NPagr

awfHH-Rural_EZ3NPmix

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ3NPmix

awfHH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr

awfHH-Rural_EZ4NPagr

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ4NPagr

awfHH-Rural_EZ4NPmix

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ4NPmix

awfHH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr

awfHH-Rural_EZ5NPagr

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ5NPagr

awfHH-Rural_EZ5NPmix

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ5NPmix

awfHH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr

Water fetching by HH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr

awfHH-SmallurbanP

Water fetching by HH-SmallurbanP

awfHH-BigurbanP

Water fetching by HH-BigurbanP

awfHH-SmallurbanNP

Water fetching by HH-SmallurbanNP

awfHH-BigurbanNP

Water fetching by HH-BigurbanNP

1.1.5 Firewood collection activities

Abbreviations

Descriptions

afwHH-Rural_EZ1Pagr

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ1Pagr

afwHH-Rural_EZ1Pmix

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ1Pmix

afwHH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr

afwHH-Rural_EZ2Pagr

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ2Pagr

afwHH-Rural_EZ2Pmix

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ2Pmix

afwHH-Rural_EZ2nagr

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ2nagr

afwHH-Rural_EZ3Pagr

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ3Pagr

afwHH-Rural_EZ3Pmix

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ3Pmix

afwHH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr

afwHH-Rural_EZ4PPagr

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ4PPagr

afwHH-Rural_EZ4Pmix

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ4Pmix

afwHH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr

afwHH-Rural_EZ5Pagr

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ5Pagr

afwHH-Rural_EZ5Pmix

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ5Pmix

afwHH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr

afwHH-Rural_EZ1NPagr

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ1NPagr

afwHH-Rural_EZ1NPmix

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ1NPmix

afwHH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr

afwHH-Rural_EZ2NPagr

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ2NPagr

afwHH-Rural_EZ2NPmix

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ2NPmix

afwHH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr

afwHH-Rural_EZ3NPagr

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ3NPagr

afwHH-Rural_EZ3NPmix

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ3NPmix

afwHH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr

afwHH-Rural_EZ4NPagr

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ4NPagr

afwHH-Rural_EZ4NPmix

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ4NPmix

afwHH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr

afwHH-Rural_EZ5NPagr

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ5NPagr

afwHH-Rural_EZ5NPmix

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ5NPmix

afwHH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr

Firewood collection by HH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr

afwHH-SmallurbanP

Firewood collection by HH-SmallurbanP

afwHH-BigurbanP

Firewood collection by HH-BigurbanP

afwHH-SmallurbanNP

Firewood collection by HH-SmallurbanNP

afwHH-BigurbanNP

Firewood collection by HH-BigurbanNP

1.1.6 Leisure activities

Abbreviations

Descriptions

aLHH-Rural_EZ1Pagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pagr

aLHH-Rural_EZ1Pmix

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pmix

aLHH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr

aLHH-Rural_EZ2Pagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2Pagr

aLHH-Rural_EZ2Pmix

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2Pmix

aLHH-Rural_EZ2nagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2nagr

aLHH-Rural_EZ3Pagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pagr

aLHH-Rural_EZ3Pmix

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pmix

aLHH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr

aLHH-Rural_EZ4Pagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pagr

aLHH-Rural_EZ4Pmix

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pmix

aLHH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr

aLHH-Rural_EZ5Pagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pagr

aLHH-Rural_EZ5Pmix

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pmix

aLHH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr

aLHH-Rural_EZ1NPagr

Leisure enjoyed by LHH-Rural_EZ1NPagr

aLHH-Rural_EZ1NPmix

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ1NPmix

aLHH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr

aLHH-Rural_EZ2NPagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPagr

aLHH-Rural_EZ2NPmix

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPmix

aLHH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr

aLHH-Rural_EZ3NPagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPagr

aLHH-Rural_EZ3NPmix

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPmix

aLHH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr

aLHH-Rural_EZ4NPagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPagr

aLHH-Rural_EZ4NPmix

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPmix

aLHH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr

aLHH-Rural_EZ5NPagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPagr

aLHH-Rural_EZ5NPmix

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPmix

aLHH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr

aLHH-SmallurbanP

Leisure enjoyed by HH-SmallurbanP

aLHH-BigurbanP

Leisure enjoyed by HH-BigurbanP

aLHH-SmallurbanNP

Leisure enjoyed by HH-SmallurbanNP

aLHH-BigurbanNP

Leisure enjoyed by HH-BigurbanNP

1.2 Commodity accounts

1.2.1 Agricultural marketed commodities

Abbreviations

Descriptions

ctef

Teff

cbar

Barley

cwhea

Wheat

cmaiz

Maize

csorg

Sorghum

cpul

Pulse

cveg

Vegetable

coils

Oil seed

ccotts

Cotton seed

ccane

Sugar cane

cfruit

Fruit crops

ctea

Tea

cchat

Chat

ccoff

Coffee

censet

Enset

ccrop

Cereal grain and other crop

cfiber

Plant based fiber

ccatt

Cattle

cpoul

Poultry and other small livestock

cmilk

Raw milk

ccott

Raw cotton

caprod

Animal product

cfors

Forestry products

cflower

Flowers

cfish

Fish

1.2.2 Industrial marketed commodities

Abbreviations

Descriptions

ccoal

Coal

cngas

Gas

cmin

Minerals

cmeat

Meat

cvprod

Vegetable

cdairy

Dairy products

csug

Sugar

cgmill

Grain mill

cgmillserv

Grain mill services

cfood

Food

cbev

Beverages

ctob

Tobacco

cmtea

Tea manufacturing

cmtob

Tobacco manufacturing

clcott

Cotton

ctext

Textiles

capar

Wearing apparels

cleath

Leather

cwood

Wood

cpaper

Paper product

coilptrl

Petroleum coal

cfert

Fertilizers

cchem

Chemicals

cminprod

Mineral

cmetal

Metals

cmprod

Products of metal

cveh

Motor vehicles

celecq

Electronic equipment

cmach

Machinery

comanu

Products of manufacturing

1.2.3 Marketed services

Abbreviations

Descriptions

celect

Electricity

cwater

Water

ccons

Construction

ctrad

Trade

chotel

Hotel

ctrans

Transport service

ccomm

Communication

cfserv

Financial service

cbserv

Business service

cpadmin

Public administration

ceduc

Education

cheal

Health

coserv

Recreation and others

crest

Real estate and renting services

1.2.4 Home consumed agricultural commodities

Abbreviations

Descriptions

cmaizo

Maize

coilso

Oil seed

cvego

Vegetable

cwheao

Wheat

cbaro

Barley

cfruito

Fruit crops

csorgo

Sorghum

ctefo

Teff

cpulo

Pulses

ccaneo

Sugar cane

cchato

Chat

ccoffo

Coffee

censeto

Enset

ccropo

Grains

cpoulo

Poultry

cmilko

Raw milk

ccotto

Raw cotton

1.2.5 Home consumed processed (industrial) commodities

Abbreviations

Descriptions

caprodo

Animal products

cforso

Products of forestry

cfisho

Fish

cmeato

Meat

cdairyo

Dairy products

1.2.6 Home consumed service commodities

Abbreviations

Descriptions

cresto

Housing

1.2.7 Water fetching commodities

Abbreviations

Descriptions

cwfHH-Rural_EZ1Pagr

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pagr

cwfHH-Rural_EZ1Pmix

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pmix

cwfHH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr

cwfHH-Rural_EZ2Pagr

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2Pagr

cwfHH-Rural_EZ2Pmix

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2Pmix

cwfHH-Rural_EZ2nagr

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2nagr

cwfHH-Rural_EZ3Pagr

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pagr

cwfHH-Rural_EZ3Pmix

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pmix

cwfHH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr

cwfHH-Rural_EZ4Pagr

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pagr

cwfHH-Rural_EZ4Pmix

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pmix

cwfHH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr

cwfHH-Rural_EZ5Pagr

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pagr

cwfHH-Rural_EZ5Pmix

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pmix

cwfHH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr

cwfHH-Rural_EZ1NPagr

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1NPagr

cwfHH-Rural_EZ1NPmix

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1NPmix

cwfHH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr

cwfHH-Rural_EZ2NPagr

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPagr

cwfHH-Rural_EZ2NPmix

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPmix

cwfHH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr

cwfHH-Rural_EZ3NPagr

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPagr

cwfHH-Rural_EZ3NPmix

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPmix

cwfHH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr

cwfHH-Rural_EZ4NPagr

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPagr

cwfHH-Rural_EZ4NPmix

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPmix

cwfHH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr

cwfHH-Rural_EZ5NPagr

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPagr

cwfHH-Rural_EZ5NPmix

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPmix

cwfHH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr

Water consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr

cwfHH-SmallurbanP

Water consumed by HH-SmallurbanP

cwfHH-BigurbanP

Water consumed by HH-BigurbanP

cwfHH-SmallurbanNP

Water consumed by HH-SmallurbanNP

cwfHH-BigurbanNP

Water consumed by HH-BigurbanNP

1.2.8: Firewood collection commodities

Abbreviations

Descriptions

cfwHH-Rural_EZ1Pagr

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pagr

cfwHH-Rural_EZ1Pmix

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pmix

cfwHH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr

cfwHH-Rural_EZ2Pagr

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2Pagr

cfwHH-Rural_EZ2Pmix

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2Pmix

cfwHH-Rural_EZ2nagr

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2nagr

cfwHH-Rural_EZ3Pagr

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pagr

cfwHH-Rural_EZ3Pmix

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pmix

cfwHH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr

cfwHH-Rural_EZ4Pagr

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pagr

cfwHH-Rural_EZ4Pmix

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pmix

cfwHH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr

cfwHH-Rural_EZ5Pagr

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pagr

cfwHH-Rural_EZ5Pmix

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pmix

cfwHH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr

cfwHH-Rural_EZ1NPagr

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1NPagr

cfwHH-Rural_EZ1NPmix

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1NPmix

cfwHH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr

cfwHH-Rural_EZ2NPagr

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPagr

cfwHH-Rural_EZ2NPmix

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPmix

cfwHH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr

cfwHH-Rural_EZ3NPagr

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPagr

cfwHH-Rural_EZ3NPmix

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPmix

cfwHH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr

cfwHH-Rural_EZ4NPagr

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPagr

cfwHH-Rural_EZ4NPmix

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPmix

cfwHH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr

cfwHH-Rural_EZ5NPagr

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPagr

cfwHH-Rural_EZ5NPmix

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPmix

cfwHH-RuralE_Z5NPnagr

Firewood consumed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr

cfwHH-SmallurbanP

Firewood consumed by HH-SmallurbanP

cfwHH-BigurbanP

Firewood consumed by HH-BigurbanP

cfwHH-SmallurbanNP

Firewood consumed by HH-SmallurbanNP

cfwHH-BigurbanNP

Firewood consumed by HH-BigurbanNP

1.2.9 Leisure commodities

Abbreviations

Descriptions

cLHH-Rural_EZ1Pagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pagr

cLHH-Rural_EZ1Pmix

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pmix

cLHH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr

cLHH-Rural_EZ2Pagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2Pagr

cLHH-Rural_EZ2Pmix

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2Pmix

cLHH-Rural_EZ2nagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2nagr

cLHH-Rural_EZ3Pagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pagr

cLHH-Rural_EZ3Pmix

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pmix

cLHH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr

cLHH-Rural_EZ4Pagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pagr

cLHH-Rural_EZ4Pmix

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pmix

cLHH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr

cLHH-Rural_EZ5Pagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pagr

cLHH-Rural_EZ5Pmix

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pmix

cLHH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr

cLHH-Rural_EZ1NPagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ1NPagr

cLHH-Rural_EZ1NPmix

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ1NPmix

cLHH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr

cLHH-Rural_EZ2NPagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPagr

cLHH-Rural_EZ2NPmix

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPmix

cLHH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr

cLHH-Rural_EZ3NPagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPagr

cLHH-Rural_EZ3NPmix

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPmix

cLHH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr

cLHH-Rural_EZ4NPagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPagr

cLHH-Rural_EZ4NPmix

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPmix

cLHH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr

cLHH-Rural_EZ5NPagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPagr

cLHH-Rural_EZ5NPmix

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPmix

cLHH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr

Leisure enjoyed by HH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr

cLHH-SmallurbanP

Leisure enjoyed by HH-SmallurbanP

cLHH-BigurbanP

Leisure enjoyed by HH-BigurbanP

cLHH-SmallurbanNP

Leisure enjoyed by HH-SmallurbanNP

cLHH-BigurbanNP

Leisure enjoyed by HH-BigurbanNP

1.3 Household accounts

Abbreviations

Descriptions

HH-Rural_EZ1Pagr

Household rural zone 1 poor agricultural

HH-Rural_EZ1Pmix

Household rural zone 1 poor mixed

HH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr

Household rural zone 1 poor non-agricultural

HH-Rural_EZ2Pagr

Household rural zone 2 poor agricultural

HH-Rural_EZ2Pmix

Household rural zone 2 poor mixed

HH-Rural_EZ2nagr

Household rural zone 2 poor non-agricultural

HH-Rural_EZ3Pagr

Household rural zone 3 poor agricultural

HH-Rural_EZ3Pmix

Household rural zone 3 poor mixed

HH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr

Household rural zone 3 poor non-agricultural

HH-Rural_EZ4Pagr

Household rural zone 4 poor agricultural

HH-Rural_EZ4Pmix

Household rural zone 4 poor mixed

HH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr

Household rural zone 4 poor non-agricultural

HH-Rural_EZ5Pagr

Household rural zone 5 poor agricultural

HH-Rural_EZ5Pmix

Household rural zone 5 poor mixed

HH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr

Household rural zone 5 poor non-agricultural

HH-Rural_EZ1NPagr

Household rural zone 1 non-poor agricultural

HH-Rural_EZ1NPmix

Household rural zone 1 non-poor mixed

HH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr

Household rural zone 1 non-poor non-agricultural

HH-Rural_EZ2NPagr

Household rural zone 2 non-poor agricultural

HH-Rural_EZ2NPmix

Household rural zone 2 non-poor mixed

HH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr

Household rural zone 2 non-poor non-agricultural

HH-Rural_EZ3NPagr

Household rural zone 3 non-poor agricultural

HH-Rural_EZ3NPmix

Household rural zone 3 non-poor mixed

HH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr

Household rural zone 3 non-poor non-agricultural

HH-Rural_EZ4NPagr

Household rural zone 4 non-poor agricultural

HH-Rural_EZ4NPmix

Household rural zone 4 non-poor mixed

HH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr

Household rural zone 4 non-poor non-agricultural

HH-Rural_EZ5NPagr

Household rural zone 5 non-poor agricultural

HH-Rural_EZ5NPmix

Household rural zone 5 non-poor mixed

HH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr

Household rural zone 5 non-poor non-agricultural

HH-SmallurbanP

Household small urban poor

HH-BigurbanP

Household big urban poor

HH-SmallurbanNP

Household small urban non-poor

HH-BigurbanNP

Household big urban non-poor

1.4 Factor accounts

1.4.1 Labor accounts

Abbreviations

Descriptions

Agrm

Agricultural labor male

Agrf

Agricultural labor female

Admm

Administrative labor male

Admf

Administrative labor female

Profm

Professional labor male

Proff

Professional labor female

Unskm

Unskilled labor male

Unskf

Unskilled labor female

Skm

Skilled labor male

Skf

Skilled labor female

1.4.2 Non-labor factors

Abbreviations

Descriptions

Capital_Land_RuralEZ1P

Capital land for rural poor in zone 1

Capital_Land_RuralEZ1NP

Capital land for rural non-poor in zone 1

Capital_Land_RuralEZ2P

Capital land for rural poor in zone 2

Capital_Land_RuralEZ2NP

Capital land for rural non-poor in zone 2

Capital_Land_RuralEZ3P

Capital land for rural poor in zone 3

Capital_Land_RuralEZ3NP

Capital land for rural non-poor in zone 3

Capital_Land_RuralEZ4P

Capital land for rural poor in zone 4

Capital_Land_RuralEZ4NP

Capital land for rural non-poor in zone 4

Capital_Land_RuralEZ5P

Capital land for rural poor in zone 5

Capital_Land_RuralEZ5NP

Capital land for rural non-poor in zone 5

Capital_Livst_RuralEZ1P

Capital livestock for rural poor in zone 1

Capital_Livst_RuralEZ1NP

Capital livestock for rural non-poor in zone 1

Capital_Livst_RuralEZ2P

Capital livestock for rural poor in zone 2

Capital_Livst_RuralEZ2NP

Capital livestock for rural non-poor in zone 2

Capital_Livst_RuralEZ3P

Capital livestock for rural poor in zone 3

Capital_Livst_RuralEZ3NP

Capital livestock for rural non-poor in zone 3

Capital_Livst_RuralEZ4P

Capital livestock for rural poor in zone 4

Capital_Livst_RuralEZ4NP

Capital livestock for rural non-poor in zone 4

Capital_Livst_RuralEZ5P

Capital livestock for rural poor in zone 5

Capital_Livst_RuralEZ5NP

Capital livestock for rural non-poor in zone 5

Non_Agg_capital

Non-agricultural capital

1.5 Other accounts

Abbreviations

Descriptions

ENT

Enterprises

GOVT

Government

TotalMargin

Transport margins

DSTOC

Stock changes

KAP

Savings

ROW

Rest of the world

1.6 Tax accounts

Abbreviations

Descriptions

LandTx

Land use tax

CapGainTx

Capital gains tax

IntIncTax

Interest income tax

RentIncTx

Rental income tax

DivTx

Dividend tax

ProfitTx

Profit tax

AgIncTx

Income tax (agricultural)

HHIncTx

Income tax (personal)

OEntTx

Other direct taxes

Impsur

Surtax from import

ImpVAT

Value added tax from import

ImpEcsTx

Excise tax from import

ImpWTx

Import withholding tax

ImpDuty

Import tax

ServTx

Service tax

LocEcsTx

Domestic excise tax

LocalVAT

Domestic value added tax

Appendix 2: Sensitivity of model results to changes in the income elasticity of leisure

2.1 Sensitivity of labor demand and production (percentage)

Labor demand by activities

Eyleisure* = 2

Eyleisure= 3

Eyleisure= 4

Agriculture

1.61

1.16

0.82

Industry

0.88

1.07

1.28

Service

0.54

0.81

1.10

Water fetching

− 21.65

− 23.56

− 24.91

Firewood collection

− 22.35

− 24.13

− 25.39

Leisure

4.62

5.63

6.34

Production by activities

Eyleisure = 2

Eyleisure = 3

Eyleisure = 4

Agriculture

1.21

0.89

0.65

Industry

0.59

0.61

0.63

Service

0.42

0.48

0.55

Water fetching

17.53

14.66

12.64

Firewood collection

16.48

13.81

11.91

Leisure

4.62

5.63

6.34

  1. Source: Author’s computation based on model results
  2. *Eyleisure: refers to the income elasticity of leisure

2.2 Sensitivity of welfare (EV/base income) to changes in the income elasticity of leisure

Households

Eyleisure = 2

Eyleisure = 3

Eyleisure = 4

HH-Rural_EZ1Pagr

6.88

6.82

6.80

HH-Rural_EZ1Pmix

6.88

6.82

6.80

HH-Rural_EZ1Pnagr

6.88

6.82

6.80

HH-Rural_EZ2Pagr

4.88

4.89

4.91

HH-Rural_EZ2Pmix

4.88

4.89

4.91

HH-Rural_EZ2nagr

4.88

4.89

4.91

HH-Rural_EZ3Pagr

5.35

5.34

5.34

HH-Rural_EZ3Pmix

5.35

5.34

5.34

HH-Rural_EZ3Pnagr

5.35

5.34

5.34

HH-Rural_EZ4Pagr

4.84

4.85

4.86

HH-Rural_EZ4Pmix

4.98

4.96

4.95

HH-Rural_EZ4Pnagr

4.98

4.96

4.95

HH-Rural_EZ5Pagr

6.94

6.76

6.64

HH-Rural_EZ5Pmix

6.94

6.76

6.64

HH-Rural_EZ5Pnagr

6.94

6.76

6.64

HH-Rural_EZ1NPagr

5.16

5.12

5.10

HH-Rural_EZ1NPmix

5.16

5.12

5.10

HH-Rural_EZ1NPnagr

5.16

5.12

5.10

HH-Rural_EZ2NPagr

3.19

3.16

3.13

HH-Rural_EZ2NPmix

3.19

3.16

3.13

HH-Rural_EZ2NPnagr

3.19

3.16

3.13

HH-Rural_EZ3NPagr

3.86

3.83

3.82

HH-Rural_EZ3NPmix

3.86

3.83

3.82

HH-Rural_EZ3NPnagr

3.76

3.75

3.74

HH-Rural_EZ4NPagr

3.46

3.41

3.37

HH-Rural_EZ4NPmix

3.46

3.41

3.37

HH-Rural_EZ4NPnagr

3.46

3.41

3.37

HH-Rural_EZ5NPagr

5.69

5.52

5.40

HH-Rural_EZ5NPmix

5.69

5.52

5.40

HH-Rural_EZ5NPnagr

5.69

5.52

5.40

HH-SmallurbanP

1.50

1.31

1.12

HH-BigurbanP

1.91

1.85

1.80

HH-SmallurbanNP

− 3.75

− 4.03

− 4.28

HH-BigurbanNP

− 1.54

− 1.72

− 1.89

  1. Source: Author’s computation based on model results

2.3 Sensitivity of macroeconomic effects (percentage) to changes in the income elasticity of leisure

 Real macroeconomic indicators

Eyleisure = 2

Eyleisure = 3

Eyleisure = 4

Absorption

2.76

2.64

2.67

Import

1.50

1.43

1.38

GDP from expenditure

2.62

2.56

2.52

Total domestic production

2.00

1.96

1.93

  1. Source: Author’s computation based on model results

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Mosa, A., Grethe, H. & Siddig, K. Economy-wide effects of reducing the time spent for water fetching and firewood collection in Ethiopia. Environ Syst Res 9, 20 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1186/s40068-020-00189-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s40068-020-00189-y

Keywords