Elsevier

Ecological Economics

Volume 179, January 2021, 106824
Ecological Economics

Analysis
Global patterns of ecologically unequal exchange: Implications for sustainability in the 21st century

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2020.106824Get rights and content

Highlights

  • We provide empirical evidence that supports the theory of ecologically unequal exchange.

  • High-income nations are net importers of embodied materials, energy, land, and labor.

  • High-income nations gain a monetary trade surplus via this resource appropriation.

  • Lower-income nations provide resources but experience monetary trade deficits.

  • The observed inequality is systemic and hampers global sustainability in multiple ways.

Abstract

Ecologically unequal exchange theory posits asymmetric net flows of biophysical resources from poorer to richer countries. To date, empirical evidence to support this theoretical notion as a systemic aspect of the global economy is largely lacking. Through environmentally-extended multi-regional input-output modelling, we provide empirical evidence for ecologically unequal exchange as a persistent feature of the global economy from 1990 to 2015. We identify the regions of origin and final consumption for four resource groups: materials, energy, land, and labor. By comparing the monetary exchange value of resources embodied in trade, we find significant international disparities in how resource provision is compensated. Value added per ton of raw material embodied in exports is 11 times higher in high-income countries than in those with the lowest income, and 28 times higher per unit of embodied labor. With the exception of embodied land for China and India, all other world regions serve as net exporters of all types of embodied resources to high-income countries across the 1990–2015 time period. On aggregate, ecologically unequal exchange allows high-income countries to simultaneously appropriate resources and to generate a monetary surplus through international trade. This has far-reaching implications for global sustainability and for the economic growth prospects of nations.

Introduction

Global use of natural resources has reached unprecedented levels and is expected to further rise in the coming decades (Krausmann et al., 2018; OECD, 2018). International trade volumes have grown rapidly (Kastner et al., 2014; Wood et al., 2018) as domestic requirements for materials, energy, land, and labor have increasingly been met by drawing on non-domestic sources (Wiedmann and Lenzen, 2018; Wiedmann et al., 2015).

The advocacy of international trade is largely premised on the notion that such trade relations are economically beneficial to all parties (Feenstra, 2015). However, this perspective neglects the material aspects of international trade flows. In contrast, the theory of ecologically unequal exchange explicitly considers material aspects of international trade and postulates that there are asymmetric net transfers of resources (including labor) from peripheral to core areas of the global economic system (Hornborg, 2019, Hornborg, 2014, Hornborg, 1998). The exclusive focus on monetary flows implies a disregard for these potentially unequal transfers of biophysical resources, such as materials, energy, land, and labor, embodied in commodities and services traded between regions with differing economic ‘power’.

High-income nations (the ‘core’ of the global economic system) depend on resource-intensive industrial technologies and infrastructures whose efficient functioning is contingent on annual net transfers of resources from distant (peripheral) areas (Frey et al., 2018; Jorgenson and Clark, 2009a). Moreover, high-income nations obtain significantly higher revenues for the resources they export than poorer nations, which is mostly due to the positions occupied in global supply chains and their respective roles in the world economy (Piñero et al., 2019; Prell et al., 2014; UNCTAD, 2013). The asymmetry of international trade, i.e. of the net transfers of resource volumes and monetary values, is a crucial determinant of the capacity of individual nations to accumulate capital and technological infrastructure and to thereby achieve economic growth (e.g., Grossman and Helpman, 1991).

Unequal trade patterns arise from and reproduce global socio-economic inequalities and hamper socio-environmental sustainability through environmental burden-shifting to poorer nations (Wiedmann and Lenzen, 2018). The displacement of extractive frontiers “elsewhere” (Schaffartzik and Pichler, 2017) is linked to socio-environmental conflicts and the rise of environmental justice movements particularly affecting the agricultural, mining, and manufacturing sectors (Temper et al., 2015) as well as commodified sinks for waste produced via economic activities (Hein and Faust, 2014).

To date, empirical evidence to support the theoretical notion of ecologically unequal exchange as a structural feature of the global economy is still very scarce. While there is a range of conceptual work (Hornborg, 2019, Hornborg, 1998) and of case studies that provide empirical evidence for the presence of ecologically unequal exchange between or within single nation states (Dorninger and Eisenmenger, 2016; Infante-Amate and Krausmann, 2019; Yu et al., 2014; Zhang et al., 2018), for specific commodities or indicators (Jorgenson, 2012; Jorgenson and Clark, 2009b), or in historical perspectives (Bogadóttir, 2016; Hornborg, 2006), comprehensive global assessments of ecologically unequal exchange over decadal time periods have not previously been undertaken. The results of the only global assessment – where ecologically unequal exchange was assessed in terms of proportionality of physical and monetary trade, ecological intensity, and net-transfers (Moran et al., 2013) – have been called into question (Dorninger and Hornborg, 2015). Given the increasingly globalized nature of the economic system and the increased focus on understanding teleconnections and sustainability (e.g., Friis et al., 2016; Seto et al., 2012), this represents a significant research gap for ecological economics and sustainability science. To fill this gap, this study assesses the international exchange of key resources at the global scale over a 26-year period (1990–2015). We quantify ecologically unequal exchange in four biophysical resources embodied in traded goods and services:

  • 1)

    raw materials, expressed in ‘raw material equivalents’ (RMEs): materials directly traded plus all materials embodied in traded goods and services (measured in Gigatons [Gt]) (Schaffartzik et al., 2015);

  • 2)

    energy: primary energy used along the whole supply chain to produce a certain good or service (measured in Exajoules [EJ]) (Owen et al., 2017);

  • 3)

    land: land use that is directly and indirectly required for the production of a good or service (measured in hectares [ha]) (Bruckner et al., 2015); and

  • 4)

    labor: all labor expended in the supply chain to produce a certain good or service (measured in person-year equivalents [p-yeq]) (Simas et al., 2015).

To facilitate a global analysis of large-scale and diverse biophysical and socio-economic flows between countries, we use aggregated indicators that capture all materials, energy, land, or labor used in global supply chains.1 In contrast to previous studies, we use biophysical resources, labor, and value added in one consistent framework and provide this in a time series analysis. Moreover, we conduct an inferential statistical testing of hypotheses derived from ecologically unequal exchange theory.

We use an environmentally-extended multi-regional input-output analysis (EEMRIO) to generate consumption-based pressure indicators (‘footprints’) in order to capture the displacement effects of international trade (Steinmann et al., 2017; Wiedmann and Lenzen, 2018). A national consumption footprint represents the domestic extraction (materials) or use (energy, land, labor) of biophysical resources within a given nation plus the net trade (imports minus exports, including embodied flows) (Wiedmann et al., 2015). The extractive expansion required for increasing trade volumes is often related to ecological distribution conflicts (Martinez-Alier et al., 2010).

In addition to the environment-related footprint assessments, we also used multi-regional input-output analysis to assess global monetary value chains and the analysis of trade in value added (TiVA). TiVA, which is sometimes referred to as a nation’s ‘value footprint’ (Wiedmann and Lenzen, 2018), accounts for the monetary value added by one country embodied in the final demand of another country, i.e. TiVA represents the monetary value a nation generates through its exports rather than the total value of the goods exported (Stehrer, 2012). The TiVA indicator is the financial counterpart to input-output-based resource footprints and follows the same calculation steps (see Section 3.2). To the best of the authors’ knowledge, the present study is the first to analyze embodied resource flows and TiVA in one consistent framework.

Our analysis is based on the most recent data available from the EEMRIO database Eora (Lenzen et al., 2012b, Lenzen et al., 2013b). In addition to direct international trade flows, EEMRIO models allow calculating embodied resource flows associated with global supply chains, by including the intermediate resources used to produce goods and services for final demand (Wiedmann and Lenzen, 2018; Wiedmann et al., 2015). We analyze the domestic extraction and use of resources and their reallocation through international trade on a global scale and in a temporal perspective. We calculate net international appropriation as well as differences in monetary valuation (TiVA) of materials, energy, land, and labor. Further, we build four structural equation models (SEM), one for each of the examined resources, to statistically assess relationships between predictive socio-economic variables, resource appropriation, and value added generation as suggested by ecologically unequal exchange theory.

Our analysis includes 170 countries, encompassing 99.2% of the world population in 2015, and the bulk of global supply chains and economy-wide resource flows. In order to investigate patterns of trade in relation to income inequality, we group countries into four income classes based on gross national income (GNI) per capita. Inspired by the World Bank’s classification of income and lending groups (World Bank, 2018a), we refer to them as high-income (HI), upper-middle income (UMI), lower-middle income (LMI), and low-income (LI) countries. However, in order to maintain similarly sized groups in terms of total population, our income boundaries deviate slightly from those of the World Bank (for details see Appendix B, Fig. 5 and Table 1).

Section snippets

The theory of ecologically unequal exchange

The only concept of ‘unequal exchange’ that is recognized by conventional economics refers to market power, that is, obstacles to the unrestrained operation of price-setting market mechanisms. The theory of ecologically unequal exchange proposes that in addition to market power asymmetries there are neglected asymmetric transfers of biophysical resources. The theory argues that such asymmetric resource flows are crucial for the capacity of cities, nations, and regions to accumulate

Materials and methods

We apply EEMRIO methodology and structural equation models (SEM) to quantitatively test the hypotheses derived from the theory of ecologically unequal exchange. As mentioned in the introduction, we group the countries of the world into four income groups based on gross national income (GNI) per capita. Separating India and China allows to form income groups of relatively even population size – which is fundamental when aiming to analyze relations between rich and poor. The high-income (HI)

Production and consumption perspectives on resources and TiVA

Across the embodied flows of materials, energy, land, and labor, the group of HI (high-income) countries used more resources from a consumption perspective than they provided through production in the year 2015 (Fig. 1a–d). Their final demand was associated with raw material requirements (including embodied resource use) exceeding their domestic extraction by 10 billion tons per year (Gt/a, 1 Gt = 109 metric tons). All regions except for HI countries were net providers of raw materials, with

Discussion: implications of ecologically unequal exchange

The theory of ecologically unequal exchange posits the disproportionate access of high-income countries to resources. Our analysis shows how the creation of (monetary exchange) value added in HI nations depends on the annual net inflow of resources from lower income regions. This observation holds true for the entire period observed, suggesting that this asymmetric exchange is a structural feature of trade relations and that economic growth in HI nations has not decoupled from such unequal

Conclusions

Our analysis highlights how mass consumption and economic growth in high-income countries are sustained by asymmetric exchange relationships with poorer regions. Ecologically unequal exchange rests on and may reinforce economic inequality between countries. The economic growth of wealthier regions is achieved through high mass throughput and concurrent environmental burden shifting to poorer regions. The richest countries in the world tend to be net-appropriators of materials, energy, land, and

Funding

This work was supported by the Volkswagenstiftung Germany and the Niedersächsisches Ministerium für Wissenschaft und Kultur (Grant Number A112269). CD was additionally funded by the Konrad Lorenz Institute for Evolution and Cognition Research. AS acknowledges financial support from the Spanish Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness, through the “María de Maeztu” program for Units of Excellence (MDM-2015-0552) and from the Austrian Science Fund (FWF) through project T 949-G27. SG and HPW

Declaration of Competing Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References (104)

  • A.K. Jorgenson

    The sociology of ecologically unequal exchange and carbon dioxide emissions, 1960-2005

    Soc. Sci. Res.

    (2012)
  • A. de Koning et al.

    Effect of aggregation and disaggregation on embodied material use of products in input-output analysis

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2015)
  • F. Krausmann et al.

    From resource extraction to outflows of wastes and emissions: The socioeconomic metabolism of the global economy, 1900–2015

    Glob. Environ. Chang.

    (2018)
  • M. Lenzen et al.

    International trade of scarce water

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2013)
  • J. Martinez-Alier et al.

    Social metabolism, ecological distribution conflicts, and valuation languages

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2010)
  • D.D. Moran et al.

    Does ecologically unequal exchange occur?

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2013)
  • A. Owen et al.

    Energy consumption-based accounts: a comparison of results using different energy extension vectors

    Appl. Energy

    (2017)
  • P. Piñero et al.

    Sector aggregation bias in environmentally extended input output modeling of raw material flows in Finland

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2015)
  • C. Prell et al.

    Uncovering the spatially distant feedback loops of global trade: a network and input-output approach

    Sci. Total Environ.

    (2017)
  • P. Samaniego et al.

    Commercial and biophysical deficits in South America, 1990–2013

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2017)
  • R. Warlenius et al.

    Reversing the arrow of arrears: the concept of “ecological debt” and its value for environmental justice

    Glob. Environ. Chang.

    (2015)
  • D. Wiedenhofer et al.

    Integrating material stock dynamics into economy-wide material flow accounting: concepts, modelling, and global application for 1900–2050

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2019)
  • R.P. Abelson

    Statistics as Principled Argument

    (2012)
  • F. Alvaredo et al.

    World Inequality Report 2018

    (2018)
  • S. Amin

    Underdevelopment and dependence in Black Africa—origins and contemporary forms

    J. Mod. Afr. Stud.

    (1972)
  • R. Bogadóttir

    Time-Space Appropriation in the Inka Empire. A Study of Imperial Metabolism

    (2016)
  • S.G. Bunker

    Underdeveloping the Amazon: Extraction, Unequal Exchange, and the Failure of the Modern State

    (1988)
  • K.P. Burnham et al.

    Multimodel inference: understanding AIC and BIC in model selection

    Sociol. Methods Res.

    (2004)
  • G.S. Cumming et al.

    Linking economic growth pathways and environmental sustainability by understanding development as alternate social–ecological regimes

    Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci.

    (2018)
  • R. Dalgaard et al.

    LCA of soybean meal

    Int. J. Life Cycle Assess.

    (2008)
  • H. Daly

    Steady State Economy

    (1991)
  • C. Dorninger et al.

    South America’s biophysical involvement in international trade: the physical trade balances of Argentina, Bolivia, and Brazil in the light of ecologically unequal exchange

    J. Polit. Ecol.

    (2016)
  • I. Dorresteijn et al.

    Incorporating anthropogenic effects into trophic ecology: predator–prey interactions in a human-dominated landscape

    Proc. R. Soc. B Biol. Sci.

    (2015)
  • P.F. Drucker

    Knowledge-worker productivity: the biggest challenge

    Calif. Manag. Rev.

    (1999)
  • A. Emmanuel

    Unequal Exchange

    (1972)
  • R.C. Feenstra

    Advanced International Trade: Theory and Evidence

    (2015)
  • M. Fischer-Kowalski et al.

    Sociometabolic transitions in subsistence communities: Boserup revisited in four comparative case studies

    Hum. Ecol. Rev.

    (2011)
  • R.S. Frey et al.

    Ecologically Unequal Exchange: Environmental Injustice in Comparative and Historical Perspective

    (2018)
  • C. Friis et al.

    From teleconnection to telecoupling: taking stock of an emerging framework in land system science

    J. Land Use Sci.

    (2016)
  • E. Galeano

    Open Veins of Latin America: Five Centuries of the Pillage of a Continent

    (1973)
  • N. Georgescu-Roegen

    The Entropy Law and the Economic Process

    (1971)
  • S. Giljum et al.

    The impacts of data deviations between MRIO models on material footprints: a comparison of EXIOBASE, Eora, and ICIO

    J. Ind. Ecol.

    (2019)
  • J.E. Givens et al.

    Ecologically unequal exchange: a theory of global environmental injustice

    Sociol. Compass

    (2019)
  • J.B. Grace

    Structural Equation Modeling and Natural Systems

    (2006)
  • G.M. Grossman et al.

    Quality ladders in the theory of growth

    Rev. Econ. Stud.

    (1991)
  • C.E. Grueber et al.

    Multimodel inference in ecology and evolution: challenges and solutions

    J. Evol. Biol.

    (2011)
  • A.L. Gulley et al.

    China, the United States, and competition for resources that enable emerging technologies

    Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci.

    (2018)
  • H. Haberl et al.

    Quantifying and mapping the human appropriation of net primary production in earth’s terrestrial ecosystems

    Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci.

    (2007)
  • J. Hein et al.

    Conservation, REDD+ and the struggle for land in Jambi

    Indonesia. Pacific Geogr.

    (2014)
  • A. Hornborg

    Global Magic: Technologies of Appropriation from Ancient Rome to Wall Street

    (2016)
  • Cited by (197)

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text