Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Risk aversion hinders forestry professionals to adapt to climate change

  • Published:
Climatic Change Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Forestry professionals’ attitudes towards risk and uncertainty under climate change, together with their perception about suitability of adaptation strategies, were investigated in Central Europe. We applied an original methodology based on lottery choices to quantify their risk and uncertainty attitude, combined with a questionnaire study about the adaptation to climate change. We tested the hypothesis that the higher the risk and uncertainty aversion of respondents, the higher the trend towards changing business-as-usual to adaptive decisions. The result falsifies the research hypothesis since uncertainty aversion has no effect, whereas risk aversion has a negative impact on the decision to adapt. We argue that risk of any change in the business-as-usual is higher than the expected risk of climate change impact in Central European forestry. We conclude that having access to novel information about expected impacts of climate change, taking into account institutional challenges and supportive experiences about useful adaptation strategies, may convince forestry professionals to adapt in the future.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This definition of uncertainty follows Knight (1921) who said that risk is a situation where the probabilities of occurrence of a damaging event are known and the associated outcomes too, while uncertainty characterizes a case where probabilities are not known precisely and outcomes are known. The uncertainty on the probability distribution of a bad event, as considered in this paper, is also known under “ambiguity” in the literature.

  2. For the extreme categories we assume 2 and − 2 under risk (as Reynaud and Couture 2012), which correspond to 2.55 and − 0.75 under uncertainty if we assume the same computation method.

  3. Only two adaptation strategies had enough « yes » and « no » answers to run a logit regression by adaptation strategy: « Assist in tree regeneration » with 45 foresters indicated they had implemented the strategy and 43 indicating they had not, and « Heavy thinning » with 28 indicated they had implemented it and 60 indicated they had not.

References

  • Alvarez L, Koskela E (2006) Does risk aversion accelerate optimal forest rotation under uncertainty? J For Econ 12:171–184

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson LR, Mellor JM (2009) Are risk preferences stable? Comparing an experimental measure with a validated survey-based measure. J Risk Uncertain 39(2):137–160

    Google Scholar 

  • Andersson E, Keskitalo ECH, Lawrence A (2017) Adaptation to climate change in forestry: a perspective on forest ownership and adaptation responses. Forests 8(12):493–512

    Google Scholar 

  • Andersson E, Keskitalo ECH (2018) Adaptation to climate change? Why business-as-usual remains the logical choice in Swedish forestry. Glob Environ Chang 48:76–85

    Google Scholar 

  • Blennow K, Persson J, Tomé M, Hanewinkel M (2012) Climate change: believing and seeing implies adapting. PLoS One 7(11):e50182

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolte A, Ammer C, Löf M, Madsen P, Nabuurs G-J, Schall P, Spathelf P, Rock J (2009) Adaptive forest management in central Europe: climate change impacts, strategies and integrative concept. Scand J For Res 24:473–482

    Google Scholar 

  • Bréda N, Brunette M (2019) Are 40 years better than 55? An analysis of the reduction of forest rotation to face drought event in a Douglas fir stand. Ann For Sci 76:29

    Google Scholar 

  • Brèteau-Amores S, Brunette M, Davi H (2019) An economic comparison of adaptation strategies towards a drought-induced risk of forest decline. Ecol Econ 164:106294

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunette M, Cabantous L, Couture S, Stenger A (2013) The impact of governmental assistance on insurance demand under ambiguity: a theoretical model and an experimental test. Theor Decis 75:153–174

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunette M, Costa S, Lecocq F (2014) Economics of species change subject to risk of climate change and increasing information: a (quasi-) option value analysis. Ann For Sci 71(2):279–290

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunette M, Foncel J, Kéré E (2017a) Attitude towards risk and production decision: an empirical analysis on French private forest owners. Environ Model Assess 22(6):563–576

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunette M, Couture S, Pannequin F (2017b) Is forest insurance a relevant vector to induce adaptation efforts to climate change? Ann For Sci 74:41

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunette M, Bourke R, Hanewinkel M, Yousefpour R (2018) Adaptation to climate change in forestry : a multiple correspondence analysis (MCA). Forests 9(1):20–34

    Google Scholar 

  • Chakravarty S, Roy J (2009) Recursive expected utility and the separation of attitudes towards risk and ambiguity: an experimental study. Theor Decis 66(3):199–228

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarke H, Reed W (1989) The tree-cutting problem in a stochastic environment: the case of age-dependent growth. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Controls 13:569–595

    Google Scholar 

  • Couture S, Reynaud A (2008) Multi-stand forest management under a climatic risk: do risk and time preferences matter? Environ Model Assess 13(2):181–193

    Google Scholar 

  • Eckel C, Grossman P (2008) Forecasting risk attitudes: an experimental study using actual and forecast gamble choices. J Econ Behav Organ 68(1):1–7

    Google Scholar 

  • Eriksson L (2014) Risk perception and responses among private forest owners in Sweden. Small Scale Forestry 13:483–500

    Google Scholar 

  • FAO (2012) Forest management and climate change: stakeholder perceptions. In: Forests and Climate Change Working Paper 11. Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Rome, Italy

  • Gollier C (2001) The economics of risk and time. The MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Gong P, Löfgren K (2003) Risk-aversion and the short-run supply of timber. For Sci 49(5):647–656

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanewinkel M, Cullmann D, Schelhaas MJ, Nabuurs GJ, Zimmermann NE (2013) Climate change may cause severe loss in economic value of European forestland. Nat Clim Chang 3:204–207

    Google Scholar 

  • Hochrainer-Stigler S, Mechler R, Pflug G, Williges K (2014) Funding public adaptation to climate-related disasters estimates for a global fund. Glob Environ Chang 25:87–96

    Google Scholar 

  • Holt C, Laury S (2002) Risk aversion and incentive effects. Am Econ Rev 92(5):1644–1655

    Google Scholar 

  • Jönsson AM, Lagergren F, Smith B (2015) Forest management facing climate change - an ecosystem model analysis of adaptation strategies. Mitig Adapt Strateg Glob Chang 20(2):201–220

    Google Scholar 

  • Kangas J (1994) Incorporating risk attitude into comparison of reforestation alternatives. Scand J For Res 9:297–304

    Google Scholar 

  • Keenan RJ (2015) Climate change impacts and adaptation in forest management: a review. Ann For Sci 72:145–167

    Google Scholar 

  • Klibanoff P, Marinacci M, Mukerjji S (2005) A smooth model of decision making under ambiguity. Econometrica 73:1849–1892

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight F (1921) Risk, uncertainty and profit. Houghton Mifflin, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • L’Haridon O, Vieider F (2019) All over the map a worldwide comparison of risk preferences. Quant Econ 10(1):195–215

    Google Scholar 

  • Lidskog R, Sjödin D (2014) Why do forest owners fail to heed warnings? Conflicting risk evaluations made by the Swedish forest agency and forest owners. Scand J For Res 29(3):275–282

    Google Scholar 

  • Lien G, Størdal S, Hardaker J, Asheim L (2007) Risk aversion and optimal forest replanting: a stochastic efficiency study. Eur J Oper Res 181:1584–1592

    Google Scholar 

  • Musshoff O, Maart-Noelck S (2014) An experimental analysis of the behavior of forestry decision-makers - the example of timing in sales decisions. Forest Policy Econ 41:31–39

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson HW, Williamson TB, Macaulay C, Mahony C (2016) Assessing the potential for forest management practitioner participation in climate change adaptation. For Ecol Manag 360:388–399

    Google Scholar 

  • Ogden AE, Innes JL (2009) Application of structured decision making to an assessment of climate change vulnerabilities and adaptation options for sustainable forest management. Ecol Soc 14(1):11

    Google Scholar 

  • Reynaud A, Couture S (2012) Stability of risk preference measures: results from a field experiment on French farmers. Theor Decis 73:203–221

    Google Scholar 

  • Sauter P, Musshoff O, Möhring B, Wilhelm S (2016a) Faustmann vs. real options theory - an experimental investigation of foresters’ harvesting decisions. J For Econ 24:1–20

  • Sauter P, Möllmann TB, Anastassiadis F, Musshoff O, Möhring B (2016b) To insure or not to insure? Analysis of foresters’ willingness-to-pay for fire and storm insurance. Forest Policy Econ 73:78–89

    Google Scholar 

  • Sauter P, Hermann D, Musshoff O (2018) Are foresters really risk-averse? A multi-method analysis and a cross-occupational comparison. Forest Policy Econ 95:37–45

    Google Scholar 

  • Schou E, Jacobsen JB, Kristensen KL (2012) An economic evaluation of strategies for transforming even-aged into near-natural forestry in a conifer-dominated forest in Denmark. Forest Policy Econ 20:89–98

    Google Scholar 

  • Sousa-Silva R, Ponette Q, Verheyen K, Van Herzele A, Muys B (2016) Adaptation of forest management to climate change as perceived by forest owners and managers in Belgium. Forest Ecosystems 3:22

    Google Scholar 

  • Sousa-Silva R, Verbist B, Lomba A, Valent P, Suškevičs M, Picard O, Hoogstra-Klein MA, Cosofret VC, Bouriaud L, Ponette Q, Verheyen K, Muys B (2018) Adapting forest management to climate change in Europe: linking perceptions to adaptive responses. Forest Policy Econ 90:22–30

    Google Scholar 

  • Spittlehouse D, Stewart R (2003) Adaptation to climate change in forest management. BC Journal of Ecosystems Management 4:1–11

    Google Scholar 

  • Uusivuori J (2002) Non-constant risk attitudes and timber harvesting. For Sci 48:459–470

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Aalst MK (2006) The impacts of climate change on the risk of natural disasters. Disasters 30:5–18

    Google Scholar 

  • Yousefpour R, Jacobsen JB, Thorsen BJ, Meilby H, Hanewinkel M, Oehler K (2012) A review of decision-making approaches to handle uncertainty and risk in adaptive forest management under climate change. Ann For Sci 69:1–15

    Google Scholar 

  • Yousefpour R, Hanewinkel M (2014) Balancing decisions for adaptive and multipurpose conversion of Norway spruce (picea abies l. karst) monocultures in the black forest area of Germany. For Sci 60(1):73–84

    Google Scholar 

  • Yousefpour R, Hanewinkel M (2015) Forestry professionals’ perceptions of climate change, impacts and adaptation strategies for forests in South-West Germany. Clim Chang 130:273–286

    Google Scholar 

  • Yousefpour R, Augustynczik ALD, Hanewinkel M (2017) Pertinence of reactive, active, and robust adaptation strategies in forest management under climate change. Ann For Sci 74:40

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful to Jens Abildtrup for his help on the econometric part of the manuscript.

Funding

This work was supported by a grant overseen by the French National Research Agency (ANR) as part of the “Investissements d’Avenir” program (ANR-11-LABX-0002-01, Lab of Excellence ARBRE).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to M. Brunette.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1. The lottery choices

Table 4 presents the ten lottery choices proposed to the forestry professionals in a risk context. We used exactly the same tables (payoffs, probabilities, bounds for risk aversion) as Reynaud and Couture (2012). For example, decision 1 corresponds to a choice between Option 1: a probability of 90% to have a payoff of €16 and 10% chance to have €20, and Option 2: 90% chance to have €1 and 10% chance to have €38.5.

Table 4 The ten lottery choices of the MPL procedure under risk
Table 5 The ten lottery choices of the MPL procedure under uncertainty
Table 6 Characterization of the preferences

Table 5 presents the ten lottery choices proposed to the forestry professionals in an uncertain context. For example, decision 1 corresponds to a choice between Option A: 50% chance to have a payoff of €35 and 50% chance to have €0, and Option B: having €25 or €0 but the associated probabilities are unknown.

The measure of the preferences corresponds to the number of safe choices to characterize risk aversion and to the number of risky choices to elicit uncertainty aversion. Table 6 presents the classification in terms of attitude towards risk and uncertainty function of the number of safe and risky choices realized, respectively.

Looking at the distribution of the numbers of safe and risky choices reveals that the higher numbers of safe and risky choices are for the neutrality threshold, respectively 4 and 5. Another observation is that 0 and 1 safe or risky choices are very rarely selected by forestry professionals so that extreme loving is not really represented in the sample. Conversely, 9 and 10 safe choices are chosen each by approximately 5% of the sample indicating extreme risk aversion. In the same vein, 9 and 10 risky choices are selected each by approximately 10% of the sample indicating extreme uncertainty aversion.

Appendix 2. The cross strategies analysis

Table 7 proposes to cross the already implemented strategies (in rows) with those planned in the near future (in columns). The letters “a” to “m” correspond to the 13 strategies proposed to the forestry professionals with: a = Plant genetically modified species, b = Assisted in tree regeneration, c = More species mixture, d = Less species mixture, e = More forest fertilization, f = Less forest fertilization, g = Longer rotation, h = Shorter rotation, i = Heavy thinning, j = Light thinning, k = More forest insurance, l = Less forest insurance, m = Other measures.

Table 7 Crossed analysis of strategies already implemented and those planned (in number)

We observe that when a strategy has already been implemented in the past (already adapted), most of time the foresters plan to continue it in the future (diagonal of italicized values). The first italicized value means then that 4 forestry professionals implemented adaptation strategy a (Plant genetically modified species) and plan to continue it in the future. In this sense, we observe that the choice of a strategy in the past is positively and significantly correlated with the choice of the same strategy in the future. For example, the choice of strategy b in the past and the choice of strategy b in the future are positively and significantly correlated at 1% (Pearson correlation coefficient: 0.578; p = 0.000). The same result applies for each strategy, except strategy c (Pearson correlation coefficient: 0.185; p = 0.126). However, sometimes, the forestry professional complements this first phase of adaptation with a new one, composed with different strategies. As a consequence, we observe that combinations of strategies emerge. For example, professionals having adopted strategy c often planned to adopt strategy b. Strategies b and c are those that have been selected the most by respondents and, they are also the strategies that have been most of time combined between them, but also with others, in particular with strategies g, h and i.

Appendix 3. Full detailed results of the two logit regressions

Table 8 presents the full results of the Model 1: logit model with a fixed effect specific to adaptation strategies and a random effect per individual, and of Model 2: logit model with only a fixed effect specific to adaptation strategies. As the random effect is not significant in Model 1 (LR test on absence of random individual effect: chibar2(01) = 1.02; Prob ≥ chibar2 = 0.1561) and as the results are similar to Model 2, we decided to present the results of Model 2 in the text. In addition, the significance of the variable in the model without individual effects increases. We found the significant variables appearing in Table 2 but also other ones. The variables called « Strat » with an associated letter correspond to the 11 adaptation strategies (13 proposed minus 2 never selected) minus the 11th (Strat_k is the less selected strategy, i.e. more forest insurance). The impact of these variables is always positive, meaning that the probability of the chosen strategy is always higher than choosing Strat_k (i.e., strategy to which the others are compared). The significant positive coefficient on Strat_a, Strat_b, Strat_c, Strat_g, Strat_h, Strat_i, and Strat_m means that these strategies are selected significantly more frequently than the Strat_k. They correspond to strategies that are more frequently selected by forestry professionals, and then, they significantly contribute to the probability of adaptation.

Table 8 Estimations of the parameters for the two logit models

We also ran a simple logit regression by adaptation strategy.

Such a logit may be performed for the strategy « Assist in tree regeneration » because this strategy is well balanced, i.e. 45 forestry professionals had already implemented it and 43 had not. The results reveal that some significant variables are the same, such as Income (parameter value = 0.724; p = 0.077) and French (parameter value = − 2.269; p = 0.006), while other appeared such as Dominant_fir (parameter value = − 2.179; p = 0.019), Private (parameter value = 2.631; p = 0.023), More_coniferous (parameter value = 2.431; p = 0.015). This means that having fir as the dominant tree species reduces the probability of assistance in tree regeneration while managing private forest and having more coniferous than broadleaved increases the propension to assist in tree regeneration.

In the same vein, a logit regression may be performed for the strategy « Heavy thinning » since it had already been implemented by 28 forestry professionals (and 60 had not implemented it). We show that the variable Income (parameter value = 0.396; p = 0.082) has a significant and positive effect on the probability to implement heavy thinning to face climate change. The variables Dominant_fir (parameter value = 0.908; p = 0.097) and Hunt_objective (parameter value = 1.645; p = 0.010) indicate that the probability to adapt is higher if hunting is one of the professional’s main objectives and if fir is the dominant tree species.

Appendix 4. The questionnaire

figure afigure afigure afigure a

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Brunette, M., Hanewinkel, M. & Yousefpour, R. Risk aversion hinders forestry professionals to adapt to climate change. Climatic Change 162, 2157–2180 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10584-020-02751-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10584-020-02751-0

Keywords

Navigation