Skip to main content
Log in

On horizontal cooperation in linear production processes with a supplier that controls a limited resource

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Mathematical Methods of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper we consider a two-echelon supply chain with one supplier that controls a limited resource and a finite set of manufacturers who need to purchase this resource. We analyze the effect of the limited resource on the horizontal cooperation of manufacturers. To this end, we use cooperative game theory and the existence of stable distributions of the total profit among the manufacturers as a measure of the possibilities of cooperation. The game theoretical model that describes the horizontal cooperation involves externalities, which arise because of the possible scarcity of the limited resource and the possible coalition structures that can be formed. Furthermore, manufacturers do not know how the supplier will allocate the limited resource, therefore, how much of this resource they will obtain is uncertain for all concerned. Nevertheless, when the limited resource is not scarce for the grand coalition, the existence of stable distributions of the total profit is guaranteed and consequently the collaboration among the manufacturers is profitable for them all. In the event that the limited resource is insufficient for the grand coalition, we introduce a new cooperative game that assesses the expectations of each coalition of manufacturers regarding the amount of the limited resource they can obtain. We analyze two extreme expectations: the optimistic and the pessimistic. In the optimistic case, we cannot reach a conclusion regarding the full cooperation of the manufacturers. In the pessimistic case, with one reasonable assumption, the existence of stable distributions of the total profit is guaranteed and as a result the collaboration among manufacturers is a win–win deal.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Similarly, it can be proved that the result holds when we consider \(v^{opt}(S)=min\{d_S,r\}\) instead of \(v^{max}\), i.e. \(C(v^{opt}) \ne \varnothing \). Note that \(v^{opt} \ge v^{max}\), but not equal in general. Therefore, when \(d_N \le r\) it will not be difficult to achieve the agreement of the grand coalition.

  2. Resource games are also used in Granot (1986), but the idea behind the resource game is different. A resource game in Granot (1986) measures the amount of a resource available to each coalition and these amounts are perfectly determined and known for all agents. In our case, the resource game measures the expectation of the different coalitions regarding the amount of limited resource they can obtain.

  3. We use this problem because it is known by hypotesis that \(\exists z\le r\) for all problems, i.e. the limited resource is not scarce in any case.

References

  • Akçay Y, Tan B (2008) On the benefits of assortment-based cooperation among independent producers. Prod Oper Manag 17:626–640

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aumann RJ, Dreze J (1974) Cooperative games with coalition structures. Int J Game Theory 3:217–237

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Cachon GP, Netessine S (2006) Game theory in supply chain analysis, in tutorials in operations research. In: Johnson MP, Norman B, Secomandi N (eds) Models, methods, and applications for innovative decision making. INFORMS, pp 200–233

  • Chakraborty T, Chauhan S, Vidyarthi N (2016) Coordination and competition in a common retailer channel: wholesale price versus revenue-sharing mechanisms. Int J Prod Econ 166:103–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen RR, Roma P (2011) Group buying of competing retailers. Prod Oper Manag 20:181–197

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen L, Zhao X, Tang O, Price L, Zhang S, Zhu W (2017) Supply chain collaboration for sustainability: a literature review and future research agenda. Int J Prod Econ 194:73–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cho SH, Tang CS (2014) Capacity allocation under retail competition: uniform and competitive allocations. Oper Res 62:72–80

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Curiel I, Derks J, Tijs SH (1989) On balanced games and games with committee control. OR Spektrum 11:83–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dutta B, Ray D (1989) A concept of egalitarianism under participation constraints. Econometrica 57:615635

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Fragnelli V, Patrone F, Sideri E, Tijs S (1999) Balanced games arising from infinite linear models. Math Methods Oper Res 50:385397

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Funaki Y, Yamato T (1999) The core of an economy with a common pool resource: a partition function form approach. Int J Game Theory 28:157–171

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Gillies DB (1953) Some theorems on n-person games. Ph.D. thesis, Princeton University, Princeton

  • Granot D (1986) A generalized linear production model: a unifying model. Math Program 34:212–222

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Gutierrez E, Llorca N, Mosquera M, Sanchez-Soriano J (2017) Equilibria in a competitive model arising from linear production situations with a common-pool resource. TOP 25:394–401

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Gutierrez E, Llorca N, Sanchez-Soriano J, Mosquera M (2018) Sustainable allocation of greenhouse gas emission permits for firms with Leontief technologies. Eur J Oper Res 269:5–15

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Krajewska MA, Kopfer H, Laporte G, Ropke S, Zaccour G (2008) Horizontal cooperation among freight carriers: request allocation and profit sharing. J Oper Res Soc 59:1483–1491

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li R, Ryan JK, Zeng Z (2017) Coorditional in a single-supplier, multi-retailer distribution system: supplier-facilitated transshipment. Prod Oper Manag 26:784–801

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu L, Qi X, Xu Z (2018) Simultaneous penalization and subsidization for stabilizing grand cooperation. Oper Res. https://doi.org/10.1287/opre.2018.1723 (forthcoming)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Meca A, Sosic G (2014) Benefactors and beneficiaries: the effect of giving and receiving on cost-coalitional problems. Prod Oper Manag 23:1549–1560

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meca A, Timmer J (2008) Supply chain collaboration. In: Kordic, V (ed) Supply chain, theory and applications. I-Tech Education and Publishing, pp 1–18

  • Mohebbi S, Li X (2015) Coalitional game theory approach to modeling suppliers’ collaboration in supply networks. Int J Prod Econ 169:333–342

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Molina E, Tejada J (2006) Linear production games with fuzzy control. Fuzzy Sets Syst 157:1362–1383

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Nagarajan M, Sosic G (2008) Game-theoretic analysis of cooperation among supply chain agents: review and extensions. Eur J Oper Res 187:719–745

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Netessine S, Zhang F (2005) The impact of supply-side externalities among downstream firms on supply chain efficiency. Manuf Serv Oper Manag 7:58–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Neill B (1982) A problem of rights arbitration from the Talmud. Math Soc Sci 2:345–371

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Owen G (1975) On the core of linear production games. Math Program 9:358–370

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Pomponi F, Fratocchi L, Tafuri SR, Palumbo M (2013) Horizontal collaboration in logistics: a comprehensive framework. Res Logist Prod 3:243–254

    Google Scholar 

  • Roma P, Perrone G (2016) Cooperation among competitors: a comparison of cost-sharing mechanisms. Int J Prod Econ 180:172–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Soosay CA, Hyland PW, Ferrer M (2008) Supply chain collaboration: capabilities for continuous innovation. Supply Chain Manag Int J 13:160–169

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thrall RM, Lucas WF (1963) n-Person games in partition function form. Naval Res Logist Q 10:281–298

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Tijs SH, Timmer J, Llorca N, Sanchez-Soriano J (2001) The Owen set and the core of semi-infinite linear production situations. In: Goberna MA, Lopez MA (eds) Semi-infinite programming: recent advances. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordretch, pp 365–386

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • van Gellekom JRG, Potters JAM, Reijnierse JH, Tijs SH, Engel MC (2000) Characterization of the Owen set of linear production processes. Games Econ Behav 32:139–156

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

First of all, the authors thank two anonymous referees and an associate editor for their helpful comments and suggestions to improve the contents of the paper. Financial support from the Ministerio de Economia y Competitividad (MINECO) of Spain and FEDER funds under Projects MTM2014-53395-C3-3-P and MTM2014-54199-P and from Fundacion Seneca de la Region de Murcia through Grant 19320/PI/14 are gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Joaquin Sanchez-Soriano.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

In this appendix we include all proofs of the results given throughout the paper. This is done in order to improve the readability of the paper for those readers not interested in the proofs, but only in the results and insights provided on horizontal cooperation of manufacturers when there is a limited resource.

1.1 Proof of Proposition 1

Given \(P\in \mathcal {P}(N),V\left( \left. S\right| P\right) =value\left( S;z_{S}(P)\right) ,\forall S\in P\) such that \({\displaystyle \sum \nolimits _{S\in P}}z_{S}(P)\le r.\) Let be \(\left( x^{S};z_{S}(P)\right) \) an optimal plan for each coalition \(S\in P\). Thus, \(Ax^{S}\le \left( \begin{array}{c} b^{S}\\ z_{S}(P) \end{array}\right) \) and

$$\begin{aligned} A\left( \sum _{S\in P}x^{S}\right) \le \left( \begin{array}{c} {\displaystyle \sum _{S\in P}}b^{S}\\ {\displaystyle \sum _{S\in P}}z_{S}(P) \end{array}\right) \le \left( \begin{array}{c} b^{N}\\ r \end{array}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Then, \(\left( {\displaystyle \sum \nolimits _{S\in P}}x^{S};{\displaystyle \sum \nolimits _{S\in P}}z_{S}(P)\right) \) is a feasible production plan for N and

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{S\in P}value\left( S;z_{S}(P)\right) \le value\left( N;\sum _{S\in P}z_{S}(P)\right) \le V\left( \left. N\right| \left\{ N\right\} \right) . \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

1.2 Proof of Proposition 2

(i):

We know that \(z_{S}(P)=d_{S}\) for all \(S\subseteq N,\) due to \(d\left( P\right) \le r\) for all P. Therefore, for each \(S\subseteq N, V\left( \left. S\right| P\right) =V\left( \left. S\right| P^{\prime }\right) \) for all \(P,P^{^{\prime }}\in \mathcal {P}(N)\) such that \(S\in P\), i.e. for each coalition the value does not depend on the coalitions formed by other players.

(ii):

Since \(d_{N}>r\) and \(d\left( P\right) \le r,\) for all \(P\in \mathcal {P}(N)\) , \(P\ne \left\{ N\right\} ,\) similarly to (i), for each \(S\subseteq N,V\left( \left. S\right| P\right) =V\left( \left. S\right| P^{\prime }\right) \) for all \(P,P^{^{\prime }}\in \mathcal {P}(N),\) i.e. the value of coalition S does not depend on the coalitions formed by other players. On the other hand, the value of the grand coalition

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{ll} \max &{} \sum \limits _{j=1}^{g}p_{j}x_{j}-cr\\ \text {s.t:} &{} Ax\le \left( \begin{array}{c} b^{N}\\ r \end{array}\right) \\ &{} x\ge \mathbf {0}_{g}. \end{array} \end{aligned}$$
(3)

only depends on its own, since there is no partition including N as a proper subset. Therefore, the related game has no externalities.

\(\square \)

1.3 Proof of Theorem 1

The dual problem of (1)Footnote 3 for the grand coalition, N, is

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{ll} \min &{} \sum \limits _{t=1}^{q}b_{t}^{N}y_{t}+0y_{q+1}\\ \text {s.t:} &{} A^{t}y\ge p\\ &{} y_{q+1}\le c\\ &{} y\ge \mathbf {0}_{q+1}. \end{array} \end{aligned}$$
(4)

An optimal solution of (1) for the grand coalition N is given by \(\left( x^{N};d_{N}\right) \) with \(d_{N}\le r,\) and the related dual optimal solution is \(\left( y_{q}^{N};y_{q+1}^{N}\right) \), where with an abuse of notation from now on, we represent by \(y_{q}^{N}\) the vector \(\left( y_{1}^{N},\ldots ,y_{q}^{N}\right) \). From duality, it is known that

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{j=1}^{g}p_{j}x_{j}^{N}-cd_{N}=\sum _{t=1}^{q}b_{t}^{N}y_{t}^{N}+0y_{q+1}^{N}=v\left( N\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, somehow, the cost of the common resource is charged to (discounted from) the value of the resources. It is easy to check that \(\left( y_{q}^{N};y_{q+1}^{N}\right) \) is feasible in the dual problem of (1) for every coalition \(S\subset N.\) Moreover, we have that for a dual optimal solution \(\left( y_{q}^{S};y_{q+1}^{S}\right) \) associated with the optimal solution \(\left( x^{S};d_{S}\right) ,\) it holds that

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{t=1}^{q}b_{t}^{S}y_{t}^{N}+0y_{q+1}^{N}\ge \sum _{t=1}^{q}b_{t}^{S}y_{t}^{S}+0y_{q+1}^{S}=v\left( S\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Thus, \(\sum _{i\in S}\left( \sum _{t=1}^{q}b_{t}^{i}y_{t}^{N}+0y_{q+1}^{N}\right) \ge v\left( S\right) ,\forall S\subset N,\) and this implies that \(\left( b^{i}y^{N}\right) _{i\in N}\in C\left( v\right) .\)\(\square \)

1.4 Proof of Theorem 2

Before giving the proof of Theorem 2 we need the following technical lemma, which is given without a proof because it is easy to derive. It give us two linear programs that, although they have different optimal solution sets, also have the same optimal values, i.e. they are optimally equivalents. Note that an optimal solution of the second one is the optimal demand of the limited resource for each coalition S\(d_{S}.\) We should highlight that they only differ in a redundant constraint, \(z\le d_{S}\), however, this is the key with which to prove the next theorem.

Lemma 1

Let \(\left( A,B,p,r,c\right) \) be an LPLR situation. For all S, the following linear programs are optimally equivalents ,

$$\begin{aligned}&\begin{array}{ll} \max &{} \sum \limits _{j=1}^{g}p_{j}x_{j}-cz\\ \text {s.t:} &{} Ax\le \left( \begin{array}{c} b^{S}\\ z \end{array}\right) \\ &{} z\le d_{S}\\ &{} x\ge \mathbf {0}_{g},z\ge 0. \end{array} \end{aligned}$$
(5)
$$\begin{aligned}&\begin{array}{ll} \max &{} \sum \limits _{j=1}^{g}p_{j}x_{j}-cz\\ \text {s.t:} &{} Ax\le \left( \begin{array}{c} b^{S}\\ z \end{array}\right) \\ &{} x\ge \mathbf {0}_{g},z\ge 0. \end{array} \end{aligned}$$
(6)

The previous result provides us with two different, but equivalent, ways in which to tackle the linear programs. In the proof of the following theorem, we use one or the other depending on which will be more helpful.

Proof of Theorem 2

Since \(d_{N}\le r\), consider the linear program (5) for the grand coalition,

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{ll} \max &{} \sum \limits _{j=1}^{g}p_{j}x_{j}-cz\\ \text {s.t:} &{} Ax\le \left( \begin{array}{c} b^{N}\\ z \end{array}\right) \\ &{} z\le d_{N}\\ &{} x\ge \mathbf {0}_{g},z\ge 0. \end{array} \end{aligned}$$
(7)

its dual is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{ll} \min &{} \sum \limits _{t=1}^{q}b_{t}^{N}y_{t}+0y_{q+1}+d_{N}y_{q+2}\\ \text {s.t:} &{} A^{t}y\ge p\\ &{} y_{q+1}-y_{q+2}\le c\\ &{} y\ge \mathbf {0}_{q+2}. \end{array} \end{aligned}$$
(8)

Let \(\left( x^{N};d_{N}\right) \) and \(\left( y_{q}^{N},y_{q+1}^{N},0\right) \) be primal and dual optimal solutions for (7) and (8), respectively with \(d_{N}\le r\) and \(y_{q+2}^{N}=0\). Effectively, by the lemma we know that linear problems (1) and (5) are optimally equivalent, and therefore their dual problems will also be optimally equivalent. Now if \(\left( y_{q}^{N},y_{q+1}^{N}\right) \) is an optimal solution of the dual problem (4) associated with the linear problem (1), then \(\left( y_{q}^{N},y_{q+1}^{N},0\right) \) is an optimal solution of the dual problem (5). Therefore, we can take a dual optimal solution with \(y_{q+2}^{N}=0\) associated with the optimal solution \(\left( x^{N};d_{N}\right) \).

Now, it is easy to check that \(\left( y_{q}^{N},y_{q+1}^{N},0\right) \) is a feasible solution for the dual problem of (5) for every coalition S. If \(\left( y_{q}^{S},y_{q+1}^{S},y_{q+2}^{S}\right) \) is an optimal dual solution associated with \(\left( x^{S};d_{S}\right) \), it holds that

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{t=1}^{q}b_{t}^{S}y_{t}^{N}+0y_{q+1}^{N}+d_{S}y_{q+2}^{N}\ge & {} \sum _{t=1}^{q}b_{t}^{S}y_{t}^{S}+0y_{q+1}^{S}+d_{S}y_{q+2}^{S}\\= & {} value(S;d_{S})\ge V(S\mid P), \end{aligned}$$

for all \(P\in \mathcal {P}(N)\). Therefore, \(\sum \nolimits _{i\in S}\left( \sum \nolimits _{t=1}^{q}b_{t}^{i}y_{t}^{N}\right) \ge V(S\mid P),\)\(\forall S\subseteq N\), and for all \(P\in \mathcal {P}(N)\) such that \((S\mid P)\) is an embedded coalition, and this implies that \(\left( b^{i}y^{N}\right) _{i\in N}\in \overline{C}\left( V\right) .\)\(\square \)

1.5 Proof of Theorem 3

Since \(C\left( R\right) \ne \varnothing ,\) there is \(u\in \mathbb {R}^{N}\) such that \(u(S)=\sum _{i\in S}u_{i}\ge R\left( S\right) ,\) for all S, and \(u(N)=r.\) Let \(y^{*}\) be an optimal solution of the dual problem of (3). From duality theory, we know that \(\sum _{t=1}^{q}b_{t}^{N}y_{t}^{*}+ry_{q+1}^{*}-cr=v^{R}(N).\) On the other hand, \(\forall S\subseteq N\)

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{t=1}^{q}b_{t}^{S}y_{t}^{*}+u\left( S\right) y_{q+1}^{*}-cu\left( S\right) \ge \sum _{t=1}^{q}b_{t}^{S}y_{t}^{*}+R\left( S\right) (y_{q+1}^{*}-c)\ge v^{R}(S), \end{aligned}$$

where the last inequality holds because \(y^{*}\) is feasible for the dual problem of coalition S and \(y_{q+1}^{*}>c\) since \(d_{N}>r\). In effect, assume that \(y_{q+1}^{*}\le c\). Consider a variation \(\varDelta r\) such that the basic feasible solution does not change and \(r+\varDelta r<d_{N}\). Then,

$$\begin{aligned} value\left( N;r+\varDelta r\right) =value\left( N;r\right) +\left( y_{q+1}^{*}-c\right) \varDelta r\text {.} \end{aligned}$$

We distinguish two cases:

  1. 1.

    If \(\varDelta r>0\), then

    $$\begin{aligned}&value\,\left( N;r+\varDelta r\right) \le value\,\left( N;r\right) \\&\quad r<r+\varDelta r<d_{N}\Rightarrow \exists \alpha \in \left( 0,1\right) \text { such that }r+\varDelta r=\alpha r+\left( 1-\alpha \right) d_{N}. \end{aligned}$$

    Since \(\alpha x^{r}+\left( 1-\alpha \right) x^{d_{N}}\) is a feasible solution for the problem with \(r+\varDelta r\), \(\left( x^{r},x^{d_{N}}\right) \) is an optimal solution for r and \(d_{N}\), we have

    $$\begin{aligned} value\,\left( N;r+\varDelta r\right) \ge \alpha value\,\left( N;r\right) +\left( 1-\alpha \right) value\,\left( N;d_{N}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

    However, \(value\,\left( N;d_{N}\right) >value\,\left( N;r+\varDelta r\right) \) by definition of \(d_{N}\) and \(value\,\left( N;r\right) \ge value\,\left( N;r+\varDelta r\right) \). Therefore, we have a contradiction.

  2. 2.

    If \(\varDelta r<0,\) then

    $$\begin{aligned}&value\,\left( N;r+\varDelta r\right) =value\,\left( N;r\right) +\left( y_{q+1}^{*}-c\right) \varDelta r\\&\quad \Rightarrow value\,\left( N;r+\varDelta r\right) \ge value\,\left( N;r\right) \text {.}\\&\quad r+\varDelta r<r<d_{N}\Rightarrow \exists \alpha \in \left( 0,1\right) \text { such that }\alpha \left( r+\varDelta r\right) +\left( 1-\alpha \right) d_{N}=r \end{aligned}$$

    Being that \(\alpha x^{r+\varDelta r}+\left( 1-\alpha \right) x^{d_{N}}\) is a feasible solution for the problem with r, \(\left( x^{r+\varDelta r},x^{d_{N}}\right) \) is an optimal solution with \(r+\varDelta r\) and \(d_{N}\), respectively. We obtain

    $$\begin{aligned} value\,\left( N;r\right) \ge \alpha value\,\left( N;r+\varDelta r\right) +\left( 1-\alpha \right) value\,\left( N;d_{N}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

    But \(value\,\left( N;d_{N}\right) >value\,\left( N;r\right) \) by definition of \(d_{N}\) and \(value\,\left( N;r+\varDelta r\right) \ge value\,\left( N;r\right) \). Thus, there is a contradiction.

Thereby we can conclude that \(y_{q+1}^{*}>c\).

Therefore, \(\left( b^{i}y^{*}+u_{i}\left( y_{q+1}^{*}-c\right) \right) _{i\in N}\in C\left( v^{R}\right) \ne \varnothing .\)\(\square \)

1.6 Proof of Theorem 4

Let \(\left( d_{i}\right) _{i\in N}\) be the individual demands of agents in N. Consider the resource game (Nw), where \(w\left( S\right) =\left( r-\sum \nolimits _{i\notin S}d_{i}\right) _{+},\forall S\subsetneq N,\) and \(w\left( N\right) =r.\)

We will distinguish two cases:

  1. (a)

    If \(\sum \limits _{i\in N}d_{i}>r\), (Nw) is a standard bankruptcy game (O’Neill 1982) and, therefore, it has a non empty core. Then, an \(u\in \mathbb {R}^{N}\) such that \(u\left( N\right) =r\) exists and

    $$\begin{aligned} u\left( S\right)\ge & {} \left( r-\sum \nolimits _{i\notin S}d_{i}\right) _{+}\ge \min \limits _{P:S\in P}\left\{ \left( r-\sum \nolimits _{\begin{array}{c} T\in P\\ T\ne S \end{array} }d_{T}\right) _{+}\right\} \\\ge & {} \min \left\{ \min \limits _{P:S\in P}\left\{ \left( r-\sum \nolimits _{\begin{array}{c} T\in P\\ T\ne S \end{array} }d_{T}\right) _{+}\right\} ,d_{S}\right\} =R^{pes}\left( S\right) . \end{aligned}$$

    Therefore, \(C\left( R^{pes}\right) \ne \varnothing \) and using the same arguments as in Theorem 3, the result holds.

  2. (b)

    If \(\sum \limits _{i\in N}d_{i}=r\),

    $$\begin{aligned} d\left( S\right)= & {} \sum \limits _{i\in S}d_{i}\ge \left( r-\sum \nolimits _{i\notin S}d_{i}\right) _{+}\ge \min \limits _{P:S\in P}\left\{ \left( r-\sum \nolimits _{\begin{array}{c} T\in P\\ T\ne S \end{array} }d_{T}\right) _{+}\right\} \ge \\\ge & {} \min \left\{ \min \limits _{P:S\in P}\left\{ \left( r-\sum \nolimits _{\begin{array}{c} T\in P\\ T\ne S \end{array} }d_{T}\right) _{+}\right\} ,d_{S}\right\} =R^{pes}\left( S\right) . \end{aligned}$$

    Thus, \(C\left( R^{pes}\right) \ne \varnothing \) and, then, from Theorem 3\(C\left( v^{pes}\right) \ne \varnothing \). \(\square \)

1.7 Proof of Theorem 5

If \(d_N \le r\), the result immediately follows by using a similar argument as in Theorem 2.

If \(d_N > r\), we first note the following:

  1. (i)

    Since the manufacturers are symmetric \(d_i=d \in \mathbb {R}_+, \forall i \in N\)

  2. (ii)

    If (xz) is an optimal plan for just one manufacturer, then by the linearity of the production system, (sxsz) is an optimal plan for s manufacturers and, consequently, \(d_S=|S|d\). Therefore, \(d >\frac{r}{n}\).

  3. (iii)

    \(R^{pes}(S)=\left( r-(n-|S|)d\right) _{+}\)

  4. (iv)

    \(r-(n-s)d \le r-(n-s)\frac{r}{n} = \frac{sr}{n}\).

Taking into account \((i)-(iv)\), it is not difficult to prove that \(\left( \frac{r}{n}\right) _{i \in N}\) belongs to \(C(R^{pes})\), therefore \(C(R^{pes}) \ne \varnothing \). Now by Theorem 3, we have that \(C(v^{pes}) \ne \varnothing \). \(\square \)

1.8 Proof of Theorem 6

Before giving the proof of Theorem 6 we need the following technical lemma.

Lemma 2

Let \(\left( A,B,p,r,c\right) \) be an LPLR situation and \((N,R^{pes})\) the associated pessimistic resource game. Each coalition configuration \(\{S_1,\ldots ,S_k\}\) is compatible.

Proof

Given \(\{S_1,\ldots ,\S _k\}\), we have to prove that

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{j=1}^{k}R^{pes}(S_j) \le r. \end{aligned}$$

First we recall that

$$\begin{aligned} R^{pes}\left( S\right) =\min \left\{ \min \limits _{P:S\in P}\left\{ \left( r-\sum \limits _{\begin{array}{c} T\in P\\ T\ne S \end{array} }d_{T}\right) _{+}\right\} ,d_{S}\right\} . \end{aligned}$$

We now distinguish two cases:

  1. 1.

    \(\sum _{j=1}^{k}d_{S_j} \le r\). In this situation, the result immediately holds.

  2. 2.

    \(\sum _{j=1}^{k}d_{S_j} > r\). First, note that this relationship implies that

    $$\begin{aligned} d_{S_h}>r - \sum _{j:j \ne h}d_{S_j} > r. \end{aligned}$$

    Now we have the following chain of inequalities:

    $$\begin{aligned} \sum _{j=1}^{k}R^{pes}(S_j)\le & {} \sum _{j=1}^{k}\min \left\{ \min \limits _{P:S_j\in P}\left\{ \left( r-\sum \limits _{\begin{array}{c} T\in P\\ T\ne S_j \end{array}}d_{T}\right) _{+}\right\} ,d_{S_j}\right\} \\\le & {} \sum _{j=1}^{k} \left( r - \sum _{h:h \ne j}d_{S_h}\right) _+ \le r, \end{aligned}$$

    where the last inequality holds because the \(\sum _{j=1}^{k} \left( r - \sum _{h:h \ne j}d_{S_h}\right) _+\) is a non decreasing function in r and when \(r = \sum _{j=1}^{k}d_{S_j}\) the left hand side equals r.

\(\square \)

Proof of Theorem 6

First, we take a maximally stable coalition \(S_1 \subseteq N\). This is always possible because in the worst case a singleton is maximally stable. Next we take a maximally stable coalition \(S_2 \subseteq N\backslash S_1\) and so on so forth. This procedure ends in a finite number of steps k and it is well defined. The coalition configuration obtained \(\{S_1,\ldots ,S_k\}\) is by construction cc-stable compatible. Indeed, Conditions (1) and (2) in Definition 2 hold by definition of maximally stable coalition. Finally, by Lemma 2 the constructed coalition configuration is compatible. Therefore, the result holds. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Gutierrez, E., Llorca, N., Mosquera, M. et al. On horizontal cooperation in linear production processes with a supplier that controls a limited resource. Math Meth Oper Res 90, 169–196 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00186-019-00667-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00186-019-00667-9

Keywords

Navigation