Skip to main content
Log in

From nest site lottery to host lottery: continuous model of growth suppression driven by the availability of nest sites for newborns or hosts for parasites and its impact on the selection of life history strategies

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Theory in Biosciences Aims and scope Submit manuscript

A Correction to this article was published on 10 February 2020

This article has been updated

Abstract

The idea that selection works in different ways during free population growth and at the equilibrium population size has been present in theoretical biology for a long time. It was first expressed as an r and K selection concept and later clarified in the debate on fitness measures in life history theory. The latest discussion related to this topic is focused on the nest site lottery mechanism and the resulting new population growth model. In this mechanistic biphasic model, the suppression of growth is induced by a shortage of free nest sites for newborns. Before it occurs, the population can grow exponentially. In this paper, the continuous version of the model and its selective properties are analysed. We show a continuous smooth transition between different fitness measures operating during the exponential growth and suppressed growth phase and at the equilibrium population size. Then, the model is extended to the case of a population of parasites, where a constant number of nest sites is replaced by the dynamics of a population of their hosts, in the role of the limiting supply. Parasite strategies are selected under exponential and suppressed growth phases of the population of hosts. Transitions between different fitness measures and conditions for extinction of hosts by parasites are analysed. An interesting result is the possibility of a continuum of fitness measures of parasites for the unsuppressed exponential growth of the host population.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Change history

  • 10 February 2020

    Unfortunately, part of the article title was updated as subtitle which in turn resulted with complete title not appearing on website and in the bibliographic data. The complete version of title is updated here.

References

  • Argasinski K, Broom M (2013a) Ecological theatre and the evolutionary game: how environmental and demographic factors determine payoffs in evolutionary games. J Math Biol 67:935–962

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Argasinski K, Broom M (2013b) The nest site lottery: how selectively neutral density dependent growth suppression induces frequency dependent selection. Theor Popul Biol 90:82–90

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Argasinski K, Broom M (2018a) Evolutionary stability under limited population growth: eco-evolutionary feedbacks and replicator dynamics. Ecol Complex 34:198–212

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Argasinski K, Broom M (2018b) Interaction rates, vital rates, background fitness and replicator dynamics: how to embed evolutionary game structure into realistic population dynamics. Theory Biosci 137:33–50

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Argasinski K, Rudnicki R (2017) Nest site lottery revisited: towards a mechanistic model of population growth suppressed by the availability of nest sites. J Theor Biol 420:279–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barbault R (1987) Are still r-selection and K-selection operative concepts? Acta Oecol 8:63–70

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlson SM, Quinn TP, Hendry AP (2011) Eco-evolutionary dynamics in Pacific salmon. Heredity 106:438–447

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Cressman R, Garay J (2003) Evolutionary stability in Lotka–Volterra systems. J Theor Biol 222:233–245

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cressman R, Garay J, Hofbauer J (2001) Evolutionary stability concepts for N-species frequency-dependent interactions. J Theor Biol 211:1–10

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Dańko MJ, Burger O, Kozłowski J (2017) Density-dependence interacts with extrinsic mortality in shaping life histories. PLoS ONE 12:e0186661

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dańko A, Schaible R, Pijanowska J, Dańko MJ (2018a) Population density shapes patterns of survival and reproduction in Eleutheria dichotoma (Hydrozoa: Anthoathecata). Mar Biol 165:48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dańko MJ, Burger O, Argasinski K, Kozłowski J (2018b) Extrinsic mortality can shape life-history traits, including senescence. Evolut Biol 45:395–404

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doebeli M, Ispolatov Y, Simon B (2017) Point of view: towards a mechanistic foundation of evolutionary theory. eLIFE 6:e23804

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engen S, Saether BE (2017) r-and K-selection in fluctuating populations is determined by the evolutionary trade-off between two fitness measures: growth rate and lifetime reproductive success. Evolution 71(1):167–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferriere R, Legendre S (2013) Eco-evolutionary feedbacks, adaptive dynamics and evolutionary rescue theory. Philos Trans R Soc Lond B Biol Sci 368:20120081

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garay J, Csiszár V, Móri TF (2017) Survival phenotype, selfish individual versus Darwinian phenotype. J Theor Biol 430:86–91

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geritz S, Kisdi E (2012) Mathematical ecology: why mechanistic models? J Math Biol 65:1411–1415

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grimm V, Railsback SFS (2005) Individual-based modeling and ecology. Princeton series in theoretical and computational biology. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hendry AP (2016) Eco-evolutionary dynamics. Princeton university press

  • Hui C (2006) Carrying capacity, population equilibrium, and environment’s maximal load. Ecol Model 192:317–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hui C (2015) International encyclopedia of the social & behavioral sciences, vol 3. Elsevier, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Hutchinson GE (1965) The ecological theater and the evolutionary play. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Kozłowski J (1980) Density dependence, the logistic equation, and r- and K-selection: a critique and an alternative approach. Evolut Theory 5:89–101

    Google Scholar 

  • Kozłowski J (1993) Measuring fitness in life history studies. Trends Ecol Evol 8:84–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kozłowski J (2006) Why life histories are diverse. Pol J Ecol 54:585–605

    Google Scholar 

  • Lion S, Metz JA (2018) Beyond R\(_0\) maximisation: on pathogen evolution and environmental dimensions. Trends Ecol Evol 33:458–473

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Łomnicki A (1988) Population ecology of individuals. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Maynard Smith J (1982) Evolution and the theory of games. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Metz JA, Nisbet RM, Geritz SA (1992) How should we define ‘fitness’ for general ecological scenarios? Trends Ecol Evol 7:198–202

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Metz J, Mylius S, Diekmann O (2008a) Even in the odd cases when evolution optimizes, unrelated population dynamical details may shine through in the ESS. Evolut Ecol Res 10:655–666

    Google Scholar 

  • Metz J, Mylius S, Diekmann O (2008b) When does evolution optimize? Evolut Ecol Res 10:629–654

    Google Scholar 

  • Pianka ER (1970) On r-and k-selection. Am Nat 104:592–597

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Post DDM, Palkovacs EPE (2009) Eco-evolutionary feedbacks in community and ecosystem ecology: interactions between the ecological theatre and the evolutionary play. Philos Trans R Soc Lond B Biol Sci 364:1629–1640

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reznick D, Bryant MJ, Bashey F (2002) r-and K-selection revisited: the role of population regulation in life-history evolution. Ecology 83(6):1509–1520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roff D (1992) Evolution of life histories: theory and analysis. Springer, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Rudnicki R (2017) Does a population with the highest turnover coefficient win competition? J Differ Equ Appl 23:1529–1541

    Google Scholar 

  • Saether BE, Visser ME, Grřtan V, Engen S (2016) Evidence for r-and K-selection in a wild bird population: a reciprocal link between ecology and evolution. Proc R Soc B Biol Sci 283(1829):20152411

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stearns S (1992) The evolution of life histories. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Traulsen A, Claussen JC, Hauert C (2005) Coevolutionary dynamics: from finite to infinite populations. Phys Rev Lett 95:1–4

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Uchmański J, Grimm V (1996) Individual-based modelling in ecology: what makes the difference? Trends Ecol Evol 11(10):437–441

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We want to thank Mark Broom, Jan Kozłowski and John McNamara for their support of the project and helpful suggestions. In addition, we want to thank anonymous reviewer for valuable comments and suggestions. This paper was supported by the Polish National Science Centre Grant No. 2013/08/S/NZ8/00821 FUGA2 (KA) and Grant No. 2017/27/B/ST1/00100 OPUS (RR).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Krzysztof Argasinski.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

The original version of this article was revised: Part of title was updated as sub-title in the original publication and corrected version of title is updated here.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Proof of Theorem 1

Let us start from subsystem (29)

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{q}}_{i}(t)=q_{i}(t)\left[ \left( \dfrac{b_{i}}{{\bar{b}}(t)}-1\right) \left( \dfrac{K}{n(t)}-1\right) /\tau -\left( d_{i}-{\bar{d}}(t)\right) \right] . \end{aligned}$$

Let us substitute \(\left( \dfrac{K}{n(t)}-1\right) /\tau ={\bar{d}}(t)+\alpha\) , which implies \(\alpha =\dfrac{K-n(t)}{n(t)\tau }-{\bar{d}}(t)\). This leads to

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{q}}_{i}(t)&=q_{i}(t)\left[ \left( \dfrac{b_{i}}{{\bar{b}}(t)}-1\right) \left( \dfrac{K}{n(t)}-1\right) /\tau -\left( d_{i}-{\bar{d}}(t)\right) \right] = \nonumber \\&=q_{i}(t)\left[ \left( \dfrac{b_{i}}{{\bar{b}}(t)}-1\right) {\bar{d}} (t)-\left( d_{i}-{\bar{d}}(t)\right) +\left( \dfrac{b_{i}}{{\bar{b}}(t)} -1\right) \alpha \right] = \nonumber \\&=q_{i}(t)\left[ \left( b_{i}\dfrac{{\bar{d}}(t)}{{\bar{b}}(t)}-{\bar{d}} (t)\right) -\left( d_{i}-{\bar{d}}(t)\right) \right. \nonumber \\&\left. \quad +\left( \dfrac{b_{i}}{{\bar{b}}(t)} -1\right) \left( \dfrac{K-n(t)}{n(t)\tau }-{\bar{d}}(t)\right) \right] \nonumber \\&=q_{i}(t)\left[ \left( b_{i}\dfrac{{\bar{d}}(t)}{{\bar{b}}(t)}-d_{i}\right) +\left( \dfrac{b_{i}}{{\bar{b}}(t)}-1\right) \left( \dfrac{K-n(t)}{n(t)\tau }- {\bar{d}}(t)\right) \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(58)

The last bracketed term can be presented in the following form:

$$\begin{aligned} \left( \dfrac{K-n(t)}{n(t)\tau }-{\bar{d}}(t)\right)&=\dfrac{K-n(t)-{\bar{d}} (t)n(t)\tau }{n(t)\tau }=\dfrac{K-n(t)\left( 1+{\bar{d}}(t)\tau \right) }{ n(t)\tau } \\&=\dfrac{1+{\bar{d}}(t)\tau }{n(t)\tau }\left( \dfrac{K}{1+{\bar{d}}(t)\tau } -n(t)\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Let us substitute the density attractor \({\tilde{n}}(t)=\dfrac{K}{\tau{\bar{d}} (t)+1 }\) in the above formula. This will lead to the form being a function of the distance from the stable density manifold measured by the bracketed term:

$$\begin{aligned} \dfrac{1+{\bar{d}}(t)\tau }{n(t)\tau }\left( {\tilde{n}}(t)-n(t)\right) =\left( \dfrac{{\tilde{n}}(t)}{n(t)}-1\right) \left( 1/\tau +{\bar{d}}(t)\right) . \end{aligned}$$

In effect, we obtain the following system:

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{q}}_{i}(t)&=q_{i}(t)\left[ \left( b_{i}\dfrac{{\bar{d}}(t)}{{\bar{b}}(t)} -d_{i}\right) \right. \\&\left. \quad +\left( \dfrac{b_{i}}{{\bar{b}}(t)}-1\right) \left( \dfrac{ {\tilde{n}}(t)}{n(t)}-1\right) \left( 1/\tau +{\bar{d}}(t)\right) \right] , \\ {\dot{n}}(t)&=n(t)\left( \dfrac{K-n(t)}{n(t)\tau }-{\bar{d}}(t)\right) , \end{aligned}$$

where the factor

$$\begin{aligned} \left( b_{i}\dfrac{{\bar{d}}(t)}{{\bar{b}}(t)}-d_{i}\right) =d_{i}\left( \dfrac{ b_{i}}{d_{i}}\dfrac{{\bar{d}}(t)}{{\bar{b}}(t)}-1\right) =d_{i}\left( \dfrac{ L_{i}}{{\bar{L}}(t)}-1\right) \end{aligned}$$

is compatible with the nest site lottery mechanism (which implies maximization of \(L_{i}=b_{i}/d_{i}\) and \(d_{i}\) among strategies with maximal \(L_{i}\)). Let us consider the second factor

$$\begin{aligned} \left( \dfrac{b_{i}}{{\bar{b}}(t)}-1\right) \left( \dfrac{{\tilde{n}}(t)}{n(t)} -1\right) \left( 1/\tau +{\bar{d}}(t)\right) , \end{aligned}$$

where the term \(\left( \dfrac{b_{i}}{{\bar{b}}(t)}-1\right)\), responsible for the maximization of \(b_{i}\), and the term \(\left( \dfrac{{\tilde{n}}(t)}{n(t)} -1\right)\) vanish with convergence to the nullcline \({\tilde{n}}(t)\). After the substitution of the switching point \({\hat{n}}=\dfrac{K}{\tau {\bar{b}}+1}\) as the population size, the replicator dynamics (29) reduce to the unsuppressed case \({\dot{q}}_{i}(t)=(b_{i}-{\bar{b}}(t))-\left( d_{i}-{\bar{d}} (t)\right)\). This means that the decrease in the coefficient

$$\begin{aligned} \left( \dfrac{b_{i}}{{\bar{b}}(t)}-1\right) \left( \dfrac{{\tilde{n}}(t)}{n(t)} -1\right) \left( 1/\tau +{\bar{d}}(t)\right) \end{aligned}$$

is responsible for the continuous transition from unsuppressed exponential growth to the nest site lottery mechanism.

Appendix 2: Proof of Theorem 2

From (39)–(40), we have

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{x}}(t)&=\frac{{\dot{n}}(t)K(t)-n(t){\dot{K}}(t)}{K^{2}(t)} \\&=\frac{1}{K^{2}(t)}\left[ \left( \frac{K(t)}{\tau }-\left[ \frac{1}{\tau } +d+D+D_{p}\right] n(t)\right) K(t) \right. \\&\quad \left. -n(t)\left( \left[ B-D\right] K(t)-D_{p}n(t)\right) \right] \\&=\frac{1}{K^{2}(t)}\left[ \frac{K^{2}(t)}{\tau }-\left[ \frac{1}{\tau } +d+D_{p}+B\right] n(t)K(t)+D_{p}n^{2}(t)\right] \\&=\frac{1}{\tau }-\left[ \frac{1}{\tau }+d+D_{p}+B\right] x(t)+D_{p}x^{2}(t). \end{aligned}$$

Thus, the function x(t) is a solution of the differential equation \({\dot{x}}(t)=P(x(t))\), where \(P(x)=\tau ^{-1}-ax+D_{p}x^{2}\) and \(a=\tau ^{-1}+d+D_{p}+B\). Note that in the above derivation, D cancels out. Therefore, every other constant or function added to D will also vanish. This means that x is independent of all host mortality factors. Since

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta =a^{2}-4D_{p}\tau ^{-1}>(\tau ^{-1}+D_{p})^{2}-4D_{p}\tau ^{-1}=(\tau ^{-1}-D_{p})^{2}\ge 0 \end{aligned}$$

we find that \(\Delta >0\), and the quadratic polynomial P(x) has two positive roots:

$$\begin{aligned} x_{*} & = \frac{a-\sqrt{a^{2}-4D_{p}\tau ^{-1}}}{2D_{p}}, \\ x^{*} & = \frac{a+\sqrt{a^{2}-4D_{p}\tau ^{-1}}}{2D_{p}}. \end{aligned}$$

The points \(x_{*}\) and \(x^{*}\) are, respectively, stable and unstable stationary solutions of the equation \({\dot{x}}(t)=P(x(t))\). We have \(x_{*}<1\). Indeed, \(x_{*}<1\) if \(a-2D_{p}<\sqrt{ a^{2}-4D_{p}\tau ^{-1}}\), leading to \(a>D_{p}+\tau ^{-1}\), which is obviously always satisfied. Furthermore, from \(a>D_{p}+\tau ^{-1}\), we find that \(2D_{p}-a<\sqrt{a^{2}-4D_{p}\tau ^{-1}}\), which yields \(x^{*}>1\). Recall that by definition, \(n\le K\); thus, we have that \(x\le 1\). Therefore, \(x^{*}\) can be rejected as nonbiological and x(t) converges to \(x_{*}\) as \(t\rightarrow \infty\).

Appendix 3: Proof of Theorem 3

We know that trajectories can converge to (0, 0) or escape to infinity. System (38)–(40) can be presented in the form

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{n}}(t)&=n(t)(b-d-D-D_{p}), \nonumber \\&\quad {\hbox {when}}\,\, n(t)\tau b \le K(t)-n(t), \end{aligned}$$
(59)
$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{n}}(t)&=\dfrac{K(t)}{\tau }-n(t)\left( \dfrac{1}{\tau } +d+D+D_{p}\right) , \nonumber \\&\quad {\hbox {when}}\,\, n(t)\tau b >K(t)-n(t). \end{aligned}$$
(60)
$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{K}}(t)&=K(t)(B-D)-D_{p}n(t). \end{aligned}$$
(61)

If condition (42) is satisfied, then we enter the suppression phase when \(n(t)\tau b>K(t)-n(t)\) and remain there. This means that for a sufficiently large time, we have the system

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{n}}(t)&=\dfrac{K(t)}{\tau }-n(t)\left( \dfrac{1}{\tau } +d+D+D_{p}\right) , \end{aligned}$$
(62)
$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{K}}(t)&=K(t)(B-D)-D_{p}n(t). \end{aligned}$$
(63)

The last system is linear, and the behaviour of its solutions depends on the eigenvalues of the matrix

$$\begin{aligned} A= \begin{pmatrix} -\alpha & \tau ^{-1} \\ -D_{p} & B-D \end{pmatrix} ,\quad \alpha =\tau ^{-1}+d+D+D_{p}. \end{aligned}$$

The eigenvalues of A satisfy the following equations:

$$\begin{aligned} (\lambda +\alpha )(\lambda +D-B)+D_{p}\tau ^{-1}=0, \end{aligned}$$

equivalent to

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda ^{2}+(\alpha +D-B)\lambda +\alpha (D-B)+D_{p}\tau ^{-1}=0. \end{aligned}$$

We have

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta&=(\alpha +D-B)^{2}-4\alpha (D-B)-4D_{p}\tau ^{-1} \\&=(\alpha +B-D)^{2}-4D_{p}\tau ^{-1} \\&>(\tau ^{-1}+D_{p})^{2}-4D_{p}\tau ^{-1}=(\tau ^{-1}-D_{p})^{2}\ge 0. \end{aligned}$$

This means that the eigenvalues of A are real numbers and the solutions of (62)–(63) are bounded if and only if \(\lambda _{1}\le 0\) and \(\lambda _{2}\le 0\), which holds if

$$\begin{aligned} \alpha +D-B\ge 0 \text { and }\alpha (D-B)+D_{p}\tau ^{-1}\ge 0. \end{aligned}$$

The last inequalities are equivalent to the following:

$$\begin{aligned} B-D\le \alpha \le \frac{D_{p}\tau ^{-1}}{B-D}, \end{aligned}$$

i.e.,

$$\begin{aligned} B-D\le & \tau ^{-1}+d+D+D_{p}\le \frac{D_{p}\tau ^{-1}}{B-D}, \\ \left( B-D\right) \tau\le & 1+\left( d+D+D_{p}\right) \tau \le \frac{D_{p} }{B-D}. \end{aligned}$$

This is the condition when the parasites “kill” the hosts, since the only stationary point is (0, 0) , meaning total extinction.

Appendix 4: Proof of Theorem 4

From “Appendix 2”, we have that the dynamics of \(x(t)=n(t)/K(t)\) are described by equation \({\dot{x}}(t)=\tau ^{-1}-a(t)x(t)+D_{p}x^{2}(t)\). Since the right-hand side is quadratic with two positive roots \(x_{*}(t)<1\) and \(x^{*}(t)>1\) (see “Appendix 2”), it can be presented in the form of the product of the roots. Describing the dynamics of x(t) as

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{x}}(t)=D_{p}(x(t)-x^{*}(t))(x(t)-x_{*}(t)) \end{aligned}$$

directly leads to (49). From (58) in “Appendix 1”, we have that the dynamics of strategy frequencies (45) can be presented in the form

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{q}}_{i}(t)=q_{i}(t)\left[ \left( b_{i}\dfrac{{\bar{d}}(t)}{{\bar{b}}(t)} -d_{i}\right) +\left( \dfrac{b_{i}}{{\bar{b}}(t)}-1\right) \left( \dfrac{ K(t)-n(t)}{n(t)\tau }-{\bar{d}}(t)\right) \right] , \end{aligned}$$

where the last bracketed term \(\left( \dfrac{K(t)-n(t)}{n(t)\tau }-{\bar{d}} (t)\right)\) can be expressed in terms of \(x(t)=n(t)/K(t)\), leading to (48).

Appendix 5: Proof of Theorem 5

Now, we should calculate the nullclines of the extended equation and their stability. The manifolds where the right-hand side of (51) equals zero will satisfy the equation

$$\begin{aligned} -D_{d}K^{2}+RK-D_{p}n=0 \end{aligned}$$

obtained from the bracketed term of (51). Here,

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta =R^{2}-4D_{d}D_{p}n \end{aligned}$$

and \(R>2\sqrt{D_{d}D_{p}n}\) is the condition for the existence of two nullclines:

$$\begin{aligned} {\tilde{K}}_{1} & = \frac{R-\sqrt{R^{2}-4D_{d}D_{p}n}}{2D_{d}} \\ {\tilde{K}}_{2} & = \frac{R+\sqrt{R^{2}-4D_{d}D_{p}n}}{2D_{d}} \end{aligned}$$

where \(K_{1}\) is an unstable extinction barrier and \(K_{2}\) is the attracting nullcline. Since the additional factor \(D_{d}K\) cannot affect Theorem 2, we can apply it and change coordinates in the system (50)–(51) from nK to xK. In effect, we obtain the system

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{x}}(t) & = \frac{1}{\tau }-\left[ \frac{1}{\tau }+d+D_{p}+B\right] x(t)+D_{p}x^{2}(t), \end{aligned}$$
(64)
$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{K}}(t) & = K(t)\left[ R-D_{d}K(t)-D_{p}x(t)\right] . \end{aligned}$$
(65)

Then, Eq. (65) has the attracting nullcline \({\tilde{K}}=\dfrac{ R-D_{p}x}{D_{d}}\), and Eq. (64) converges to \(x_{*}\). Combining them leads to equilibrium \(x_{*}\) and \({\hat{K}}=\dfrac{ R-D_{p}x_{*}}{D_{d}}\), which is positive for \(R>D_{p}x_{*}\).

Appendix 6: Proof of Theorem 6

Note that in the system (55)–(57), in addition to the strategy specific parasite mortalities \(d_{i}\), we have additional mortalities caused by the death of the host equal to \(D-D_{p}-D_{d}K(t)\). We can incorporate them into aggregated mortalities \(d_{i}^{A}(K(t))=d_{i}+D+D_{p}+D_{d}K(t)\) (and thus, \({\bar{d}}^{A}(t,K(t))={\bar{d}} (t)+D+D_{p}+D_{d}K(t)\)). Then, analogously to (58) from “Appendix 1” and (48), the frequency dynamics can be presented as

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{q}}_{i}(t) & = q_{i}(t)\left[ \left( b_{i}-{\bar{b}}(t)\right) \left( \dfrac{K(t)-n(t)}{n(t)\tau {\bar{b}}(t)}\right) \right. \\&\quad \left. -\left( d_{i}^{A}(K(t))-{\bar{d}} ^{A}(t,K(t))\right) \right] = \\ & = q_{i}(t)\left[ \left( b_{i}\dfrac{{\bar{d}}^{A}(t,K(t))}{{\bar{b}}(t)} -d_{i}^{A}(K(t))\right) \right. \\&\quad \left. +\left( \dfrac{b_{i}}{{\bar{b}}(t)}-1\right) \left( \dfrac{K(t)}{n(t)\tau }-\tau ^{-1}-{\bar{d}}^{A}(t,K(t))\right) \right] . \end{aligned}$$

On the nullcline \({\tilde{n}}(t,K(t))\) (52), where the bracketed term of the r.h.s of the parasite population size equation (56) is zero, we have that \({\tilde{x}}(t,K(t))={\tilde{n}}(t,K(t))/K(t)\), and in effect, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} 1/{\tilde{x}}(t,K(t))\tau & = \dfrac{K(t)}{{\tilde{n}}(t,K(t))\tau }\\& =\tau ^{-1}+ {\bar{d}}(t) +D+D_{p}+D_{d}K(t) \\& =\tau ^{-1}+{\bar{d}}^{A}(t,K(t)), \end{aligned}$$

and this factor is an increasing function of K. Then, the frequency dynamics can be presented as

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{q}}_{i}(t) & = q_{i}(t)\left[ \left( b_{i}\dfrac{{\bar{d}}^{A}(t,K(t))}{{\bar{b}} (t)}-d_{i}^{A}(K(t))\right) \right. \\&\left. +\left( \dfrac{b_{i}}{{\bar{b}}(t)}-1\right) \left( \dfrac{1}{x(t)\tau }-\dfrac{1}{{\tilde{x}}(t,K(t))\tau }\right) \right] \end{aligned}$$

Recall the proof of Theorem 2. Therefore, we can replace Eq. (56) by the equation

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{x}}(t)=-D_{p}(x(t)-x^{*}(t))(x(t)-x_{*}(t)) \end{aligned}$$

as in Theorems 4 and 5. Then, the factor \(\dfrac{1}{ x(t)\tau }\) will be attracted by \(\dfrac{1}{x_{*}(t)\tau }\). Similar to Theorem 5, Eq. (57) can be denoted in terms of x(t) as

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{K}}(t)=K(t)\left[ B-D-D_{d}K(t)-D_{p}x(t)\right] . \end{aligned}$$

Thus, the density subsystem (56)–(57) is attracted by \(x_{*}(t)\) and \({\hat{K}}(t)=\dfrac{R-D_{p}x_{*}(t)}{D_{d}}\), and \(R\le D_{p}x_{*}(t)\) is the condition for evolutionary suicide.

Now, fix the value of q(t) and focus on the subspace nK (which can be presented as xK). For each particular point q, we have a specific value of \({\bar{d}}(q)\). From Theorem 5, we know that for every fixed value of d, a unique stable equilibrium \(x_{*}\) exists, which determines the respective stable value of \({\hat{K}}\). Since this is a stationary point, it should be the intersection of the attracting nullcline \({\tilde{n}}(t,K)\) and the attracting nullcline \({\tilde{K}}_{2}\) (54) from Theorem 5. Therefore, at this point, we have that \(x_{*}={\tilde{x}}(t,{\hat{K}})\) and in effect

$$\begin{aligned} \left( \dfrac{1}{x(t)\tau }-\dfrac{1}{{\tilde{x}}(t,K(t))\tau }\right) =0. \end{aligned}$$
(66)

For every value of q from the strategy simplex, we can define point \(x_{*}\), and for that point, we can define the respective \({\hat{K}}\). Both \(x_{*}\) and \({\hat{K}}\) constitute, respectively, the attracting surfaces for system (56, 57). Since \({\hat{K}}\) depends only on \(x_{*}\), which in turn depends on the value of \({\bar{d}}\) determined by the strategic composition of the population q(t), these attracting surfaces can be described as

$$\begin{aligned} \breve{x}_{*}(q) & = \frac{a(q)-\sqrt{a(q)^{2}-4D_{p}\tau ^{-1}}}{2D_{p}} ,\\ \quad {\hbox {where}}\,\, a(q) & = \tau ^{-1}+{\bar{d}}(q)+D_{p}+B, \\ \breve{K}(q) & = \dfrac{R-D_{p}\breve{x}_{*}(q)}{D_{d}}. \end{aligned}$$

On the surface \(\left( \breve{x}_{*}(q),\breve{K}(q)\right)\), condition (66) is always satisfied, leading to the pure nest site lottery mechanism operating there.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Argasinski, K., Rudnicki, R. From nest site lottery to host lottery: continuous model of growth suppression driven by the availability of nest sites for newborns or hosts for parasites and its impact on the selection of life history strategies. Theory Biosci. 139, 171–188 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12064-019-00307-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12064-019-00307-0

Keywords

Navigation