Skip to main content
Log in

Forward transition rates

  • Published:
Finance and Stochastics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The idea of forward rates stems from interest rate theory. It has natural connotations to transition rates in multi-state models. The generalisation from the forward mortality rate in a survival model to multi-state models is non-trivial and several definitions have been proposed. We establish a theoretical framework for the discussion of forward rates. Furthermore, we provide a novel definition with its own logic and merits and compare it with the proposals in the literature. The definition turns the Kolmogorov forward equations inside out by interchanging the transition probabilities with the transition intensities as the object to be calculated.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  1. Bauer, D., Benth, F., Kiesel, R.: Modeling the forward surface of mortality. SIAM J. Financ. Math. 3, 639–666 (2012)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  2. Buchardt, K.: Dependent interest and transition rates in life insurance. Insur. Math. Econ. 55, 167–179 (2014)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  3. Buchardt, K.: Continuous affine processes: transformations, Markov chains and life insurance. Adv. Appl. Probab. 48, 423–442 (2016)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  4. Buchardt, K.: Kolmogorov’s forward PIDE and forward transition rates in life insurance. Scand. Actuar. J. 2017, 377–394 (2017)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  5. Buchardt, K., Møller, T.: Life insurance cash flows with policyholder behavior. Risks 2015, 290–317 (2015)

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  6. Christiansen, M., Niemeyer, A.: On the forward rate concept in multi-state life insurance. Finance Stoch. 19, 295–327 (2015)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  7. Dahl, M.: Stochastic mortality in life insurance: market reserves and mortality-linked insurance contracts. Insur. Math. Econ. 35, 113–136 (2004)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  8. Dahl, M., Møller, T.: Valuation and hedging of life insurance liabilities with systematic mortality risk. Insur. Math. Econ. 39, 193–217 (2006)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  9. Duffie, D., Pan, J., Singleton, K.: Transform analysis and asset pricing for affine jump-diffusions. Econometrica 68, 1343–1376 (2000)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  10. Heath, D., Jarrow, R., Morton, A.: Bond pricing and the term structure of interest rates. Econometrica 60, 77–106 (1992)

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  11. Henriksen, L.: Aspects of valuation and optimization in life insurance. Ph.D. thesis, University of Copenhagen (2014). Available online http://web.math.ku.dk/noter/filer/phd14lfbh.pdf

  12. Hoem, J.: Markov chain models in life insurance. Blätter DGVFM 9, 91–107 (1969)

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  13. Jacobsen, M.: Point Process Theory and Applications: Marked Point and Piecewise Deterministic Processes. Probability and Its Applications. Birkhäuser, Basel (2006)

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  14. Kallenberg, O.: Foundations of Modern Probability, 1st edn. Probability and Its Applications. Springer, Berlin (1997)

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  15. Kraft, H., Steffensen, M.: Bankruptcy, counterparty risk, and contagion. Rev. Finance 11, 209–252 (2007)

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  16. Milevsky, M., Promislow, D.: Mortality derivatives and the option to annuitise. Insur. Math. Econ. 29, 299–318 (2001)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  17. Miltersen, K., Persson, S.: Is mortality dead? Stochastic forward force of mortality rate determined by no arbitrage. Working paper, Norwegian School of Economics and Business Administration (2005). Available online at http://www.mathematik.uni-ulm.de/carfi/vortraege/downloads/DeadMort.pdf

  18. Møller, T., Steffensen, M.: Market-Valuation Methods in Life and Pension Insurance. International Series on Actuarial Science. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (2007)

    Book  MATH  Google Scholar 

  19. Norberg, R.: Reserves in life and pension insurance. Scand. Actuar. J. 1991, 3–24 (1991)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  20. Norberg, R.: Forward mortality and other vital rates—are they the way forward? Insur. Math. Econ. 47, 105–112 (2010)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Christian Furrer’s research is partly funded by the Innovation Fund Denmark (IFD) under File No. 7038-00007B. We should like to thank Lars Frederik Brandt for fruitful discussions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Christian Furrer.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix: Proofs

Appendix: Proofs

Before we prove Lemma 2.1, we recall the so-called chain rule for conditional independence; see e.g. [14, Proposition 5.8]. Let \(\mathcal{G}_{1}\), \(\mathcal{G}_{2}\), \(\mathcal{K}\) and ℋ be sub-\(\sigma \)-algebras. The chain rule states that

if and only if

If \(\mathcal{G}_{1} \subseteq \mathcal{G}_{2}\), we find that

which is called reduction, and

(A.1)

Proof of Lemma 2.1

Because \(X\) is Markovian conditionally on \(\mu \), it holds that

(A.2)

Furthermore, by construction, the conditional distribution of \((X_{s})_{s\leq t}\) given \(\mathcal{F}^{\mu }_{\infty }\) is \(\mathcal{F}_{[0,t]}^{\mu }\)-measurable; it is only a function of \(\mu \) through \((\mu _{s})_{s \leq t}\), see the properties of the (conditional) transition probabilities \(P_{jk}^{\mu }\). It follows from [14, Proposition 5.6] that

Then by reduction,

(A.3)

which proves the first part of the result. Beginning with (A.3), apply (A.1) to obtain

(A.4)

Let \(\mathcal{K} = \mathcal{F}_{[0,t]}^{X}\), \(\mathcal{H} = \sigma (X _{t}) \vee \mathcal{F}_{[0,t]}^{\mu }\), \(\mathcal{G}_{1} = \mathcal{F}_{(t,\infty )}^{\mu }\) and \(\mathcal{G}_{2} = \mathcal{F} _{(t,\infty )}^{X}\). Recall that \(\mathcal{F}_{\infty }^{\mu }= \mathcal{F}_{[0,t]}^{\mu }\vee \mathcal{F}_{(t,\infty )}^{\mu }\). We might recast (A.4) and (A.2) as

and then it follows from the chain rule that

This exactly reads

which establishes the second part of the result, completing the proof. □

Proof of Theorem 3.2

We first show that there exists a unique solution to (3.5) for any \(T \in (t, \infty )\). Fix \(T\). In what follows, we suppress \(t\) notationally.

With \(m_{jj} := - \sum _{k \neq j} m_{jk}\), we can rewrite (3.5) as

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial }{\partial T}{\mathcal{P}}(T) = {\mathcal{P}}(T) {m}(T), \end{aligned}$$
(A.5)

with \(\frac{\partial }{\partial T}{\mathcal{P}}\), \({\mathcal{P}}\) and \({m}\) being the corresponding matrices. Because \(\mathcal{P}_{jk}(T) = 0\) for \(k < j\), it follows that \({\mathcal{P}}(T)\) is an upper triangular matrix with diagonal elements \(\mathcal{P}_{jj}(T)\). Now note that

$$\begin{aligned} P_{jj}^{\mu }(T) = \exp \bigg(-\int _{t}^{T} \sum _{k > j} \mu _{jk}(s) \, \mathrm{d}s \bigg) > 0. \end{aligned}$$

Consequently, we have \(\mathcal{P}_{jj}(T)>0\) and in particular

$$\begin{aligned} \det {\mathcal{P}}(T) = \prod _{j=0}^{J} \mathcal{P}_{jj}(T) > 0. \end{aligned}$$

This implies that \({\mathcal{P}}(T)\) is invertible with inverse \({\mathcal{P}}^{-1}(T)\), which is also an upper triangular matrix. Hence (A.5) has a unique solution given by

$$\begin{aligned} {m}(T) = {\mathcal{P}}^{-1}(T)\frac{\partial }{\partial T}{\mathcal{P}}(T). \end{aligned}$$

Note that

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{k \neq j} m_{jk}(T) &= \sum _{k \neq j} \sum _{\ell } \mathcal{P} ^{-1}_{j\ell }(T)\frac{\partial }{\partial T}{\mathcal{P}}_{\ell k}(T) \\ &= \sum _{\ell } \mathcal{P}^{-1}_{j\ell }(T) \frac{\partial }{\partial T} \sum _{k \neq j} {\mathcal{P}}_{\ell k}(T) \\ &= -\sum _{\ell } \mathcal{P}^{-1}_{j\ell }(T) \frac{\partial }{ \partial T} {\mathcal{P}}_{\ell j}(T) = -m_{jj}(T), \end{aligned}$$

according to the definition at the beginning of the proof. This completes the proof of existence and uniqueness.

To complete the proof, we have to show that the solution is \(\mathcal{F}_{t}^{\mu }\)-measurable (as a function of \(T\)). This follows immediately by e.g. Cramér’s rule because the entries of \({\mathcal{P}}\) are \(\mathcal{F}_{t}^{\mu }\)-measurable.

If \(T \mapsto \frac{\partial }{\partial T}\mathcal{P}(t,T)\) is assumed to be continuous, it follows by similar arguments and an application of e.g. Cramér’s rule that the solution is also continuous. □

Forward transition rates in the survival model with surrender and free policy We consider the state-wise forward transition rates given by (4.2). Because \(\psi \) and \(\sigma \) are deterministic, the only non-trivial derivations are related to \(m_{13}\) and \(m_{14}\). By setting \(\sigma =0\) and using symmetry, the derivation of \(m_{14}\) follows from the derivation of \(m_{13}\). Hence it suffices to derive \(m_{13}\). On \(\{X_{t} = 1\}\), it holds that

and

Consequently,

$$\begin{aligned} m_{13}(t,T) &= \sigma (T) + \frac{ \mathbb{E} [ e^{-\int _{(t,T]} ( \eta (s) + \rho (s)) \, \mathrm{d}s} \rho (T) \, | \mathcal{F}^{ \eta ,\rho }_{t}] }{ \mathbb{E} [ e^{-\int _{(t,T]} (\eta (s) + \rho (s)) \, \mathrm{d}s} | \mathcal{F}^{\eta ,\rho }_{t}] } \end{aligned}$$

on \(\{X_{t} = 1\}\). Let now \(C\) be defined by

$$\begin{aligned} C(t,T) = \int _{(t,T]} e^{-\int _{(t,s]} \psi (u) \, \mathrm{d}u} \psi (s) e^{-\int _{(s,T]} \sigma (u) \, \mathrm{d}u} \, \mathrm{d}s. \end{aligned}$$

Note that on \(\{X_{t} = 0\}\),

Thus whenever \(\psi \) is strictly positive on a subset of \((t,T]\) with non-zero Lebesgue measure, it holds on \(\{X_{t} = 0\}\) that

$$\begin{aligned} m_{13}(t,T) &= \frac{ \mathbb{E} [ e^{-\int _{(t,T]} (\eta (s) + \rho (s)) \, \mathrm{d}s} (\rho (T) + \sigma (T)) \, | \mathcal{F} ^{\eta ,\rho }_{t}] }{ \mathbb{E} [ e^{-\int _{(t,T]} (\eta (s) + \rho (s)) \, \mathrm{d}s} \, | \mathcal{F}^{\eta ,\rho }_{t}] } \\ &= \sigma (T) + \frac{ \mathbb{E} [ e^{-\int _{(t,T]} (\eta (s) + \rho (s)) \, \mathrm{d}s} \rho (T) \, | \mathcal{F}^{\eta ,\rho }_{t}] }{ \mathbb{E} [ e^{-\int _{(t,T]} (\eta (s) + \rho (s)) \, \mathrm{d}s} | \mathcal{F}^{\eta ,\rho }_{t}] }, \end{aligned}$$

as the terms involving \(C(t,T)\) cancel. To conclude, this shows that

$$\begin{aligned} m_{13}(t,T) = \sigma (T) + \frac{ \mathbb{E} [ e^{-\int _{(t,T]} ( \eta (s) + \rho (s)) \, \mathrm{d}s} \rho (T) \, | \mathcal{F}^{ \eta ,\rho }_{t}] }{ \mathbb{E} [ e^{-\int _{(t,T]} (\eta (s) + \rho (s)) \, \mathrm{d}s} | \mathcal{F}^{\eta ,\rho }_{t}] } \end{aligned}$$

is an \(\mathcal{F}_{t}^{\eta ,\rho }\)-measurable version of the state-wise forward transition rates. □

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Buchardt, K., Furrer, C. & Steffensen, M. Forward transition rates. Finance Stoch 23, 975–999 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00780-019-00397-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00780-019-00397-0

Keywords

Mathematics Subject Classification (2010)

JEL Classification

Navigation