Skip to main content
Log in

Micro and Macro Resilience Measures of an Economic Crisis

  • Published:
Networks and Spatial Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Using Italian Households Budget Survey data over the period 1997-2013, a Cragg model in a life-cycle context is specified to compare the consumption behaviour in the pre- and post-crisis time and develop different micro and macro measures of resilience against crisis shocks. Cohort profiles for participation in and for consumption of tourism services in the pre- and post-crisis time are determined so as to explore the households’ resilience by generations. Next, the households’ resilience according to socio-demographic characteristics is addressed. As for the macro-resilience, combining individual expenditure elasticity, we examine whether and how Italian regions have responded to the recent economic crisis.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The term “resilience” was traditionally used in geology, biology and psychology, but it is now also gaining popularity in regional studies. For a more extensive analysis of the development of the notion of resilience in regional and local economic studies, we refer to Martin and Sunley (2015), Ösht el at. (2018).

  2. The North East and North West were jointly analysed, so throughout the paper we refer to them as North regions.

  3. Data is taken from the Trips and Holidays survey carried out yearly by ISTAT. It is retrieved at: http://dati.istat.it. The analysis has been limited to trips for personal purposes.

  4. Data on the expenditure of Italian households has been drawn from the Household Budget Survey (HBS) that is carried out by ISTAT.

  5. The selection of the socio-demographic variables has been driven by preliminary empirical evidence on the Italian context (see Brandolini 2014; Jenkins et al. 2013; Rodano and Rondinelli 2014).

  6. As previously mentioned, due to data availability, we use total household expenditure as a proxy of income, so the associated parameter measures the expenditure elasticity.

  7. For details about the Cragg model, see Appendix 1.

  8. To model the life cycle profile, we use the logarithm of age that – as shown in Figure 2 – is better able to model tourism consumption over the life cycle and the logarithm of generation (Browning et al. 2016; Aguiar and Hurst 2013).

  9. As our empirical model does not include price variables, it is plausible ask whether this evidence might be also due to an increase in the price of tourism goods, which may negatively affect the decision to spend on tourism. However, the dynamic of the consumer price index for both accommodation and leisure does not support this interpretation. We would like to thank an anonymous referee for this suggestion and interpretation.

  10. For a discussion of the Cragg approach in tourism expenditure modeling, see Bernini and Cracolici (2015) and Bernini et al. (2017b).

  11. For each household member, HBF surveys the individual’s age by using a categorical variable subdivided in 15 age-classes. We provide some robust checks to support the use of the mid-range age-class value as the householder’s age. The distribution of individuals within each age-class is quite uniform, largely supporting the use of the median value. Results are available from the Authors on request.

References

  • Aguiar M, Hurst E (2013) Deconstructing lifecycle expenditure. J Polit Econ 121:437–492

    Google Scholar 

  • Alegre J, Mateo S, Pou L (2010) An analysis of households’ appraisal of their budget constraints for potential participation in tourism. Tour Manag 31:45–56

    Google Scholar 

  • Alegre J, Mateo S, Pou L (2013) Tourism participation and expenditure by Spanish households: The effects of the economic crisis and unemployment. Tour Manag 39:37–49

    Google Scholar 

  • Attanasio O, Weber G (1994) The UK consumption boom of the late 1980s: aggregate implications of microeconomic evidence. Econ J 104(427):1269–1302

    Google Scholar 

  • Attanasio O, Banks J, Meghir C, Weber G (1999) Humps and bumps in lifetime consumption. J Bus Econ Stat 17:22–35

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergström J, Dekker SWA (2014) Bridging the Macro and the Micro by Considering the Meso: Reflections on the Fractal Nature of Resilience. Ecol Soc 19(4):22–31

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernini C, Cracolici MF (2016) Is participation in the tourism market an opportunity for everyone? Some evidence from Italy. Tour Econ 22(1):57–79

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernini C, Cracolici MF (2015) Demographic Change, Tourism Expenditure and Life Cycle Behavior. Tour Manag 47:191–205

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernini C, Cracolici MF, Viroli C (2017a) Does Tourism Consumption Behaviour Mirror Differences in Living Standards? Soc Indic Res 134(3):1157–1171

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernini C, Cracolici MF, Nijkamp P (2017b) Place-Based Attributes and Spatial Expenditure Behavior in Tourism. J Reg Sci 57(2):218–244

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernini C, Guizzardi A, Angelini G (2013) DEA-like model and common weights approach for the construction of a subjective community well-being indicator. Soc Indic Res 114:405–424

    Google Scholar 

  • Bono F, Cracolici MF, Cuffaro M (2017) A Hierarchical Model for Analysing Consumption Patterns in Italy Before and During the Great Recession. Soc Indic Res 134(2):421–436

    Google Scholar 

  • Brandolini A (2014) The Big Chill. Italian Family Budgets after the Great Recession. Italian Politics:233–256. https://doi.org/10.3167/ip.2014.290114

  • Bronner F, de Hoog R (2014) Vacationers and the economic “double dip” in Europe. Tour Manag 40:330–337

    Google Scholar 

  • Bronner F, de Hoog R (2016) Crisis Resistance of Tourist Demand: The Importance of Quality of Life. J Travel Res 55(2):190–204

    Google Scholar 

  • Browning M, Crossley F, Lührmann M (2016) Durable Purchases over the Later Life Cycle. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 78:145–169

    Google Scholar 

  • Browning M, Deaton A, Irish M (1985) A profitable approach to labor supply and commodity demands over the life-cycle. Econometrica 53:503–543

    Google Scholar 

  • Capello R, Caragliu A, Fratesi U (2015) Spatial heterogeneity in the costs of the economic crisis in Europe: are cities sources of regional resilience? J Econ Geogr 15:951–972

    Google Scholar 

  • Caschili S, Reggiani A, Medda F (2015) Resilience and Vulnerability of Spatial Economic Networks. Netw Spat Econ 15:205–210

    Google Scholar 

  • Cracolici MF, Giambona F, Cuffaro M (2013) Family structure and subjective economic well-being: some new evidence. Soc Indic Res 118(1):433–456

    Google Scholar 

  • Cragg J (1971) Some Statistical Models for Limited Dependent Variables with Application to the Demand for Durable Goods. Econometrica 39:829–844

    Google Scholar 

  • Crescenzi R, Luca D, Milio S (2016) The Geography of the Economic Crisis in Europe: National Macroeconomic Conditions, Regional Structural Factors and Short-term Economic Performance. Camb J Reg Econ Soc 9:13–32

    Google Scholar 

  • Deaton A (1985) Panel Data from Time Series of Cross Sections. J Econ 30:109–126

    Google Scholar 

  • Deaton A (1997) The Analysis of Household Surveys: A Microeconometric Approach to Development Policy. Johns Hopkins Univ. Press (for World Bank, Baltimore

    Google Scholar 

  • Deaton A, Paxson C (1994) Intertemporal choice and inequality. J Polit Econ 102:437–467

    Google Scholar 

  • Dolnicar S, Yanamandram V, Clif K (2012) The Contribution of Vacations to Quality of Life. Ann Tour Res 39(1):59–83

    Google Scholar 

  • Doran J, Fingleton B (2015) Resilience from the micro perspective. Camb J Reg Econ Soc 8:205–223

    Google Scholar 

  • Eugenio-Martin JL, Campos-Soria JA (2011) Income and the substitution pattern between domestic and international tourism demand. Appl Econ 43(20):2519–2531

    Google Scholar 

  • Eugenio-Martin JL, Campos-Soria JA (2014) Economic crisis and tourism expenditure cutback decision. Ann Tour Res 44:53–73

    Google Scholar 

  • Fingleton B, Garretsen H, Martin R (2012) Recessionary shocks and regional employment: evidence on the resilience of U.K. regions. J Reg Sci 52:109–133

    Google Scholar 

  • Foster KA (2007) A case study approach to understanding regional resilience. Working Paper 2007–08. Institute of Urban and Regional Development, Berkeley

    Google Scholar 

  • Gunderson LH, Holling CS (2002) Panarchy: Understanding Transformations in Human and Natural Systems. Island, Washington, D.C.

    Google Scholar 

  • Griffith D, Chun Y (2015) Spatial Autocorrelation in Spatial Interactions Models: Geographic Scale and Resolution Implications for Network Resilience and Vulnerability. Netw Spat Econ 15:337–365

    Google Scholar 

  • Hill RP, Martin KD (2012) Absolute and relative restriction and consumer behavior: Implications for understanding global consumption. J Consum Aff 46(1):37–61

    Google Scholar 

  • Hill EW, Wial H, Wolman H (2008) Exploring regional economic resilience. Working Paper 2008–04. Institute of Urban and Regional Development, Berkeley

    Google Scholar 

  • Jang S, Ham S (2009) A double-hurdle analysis of travel expenditure: Baby boomer seniors versus older seniors. Tour Manag 30:372–380

    Google Scholar 

  • Jenkins SP, Brandolini A, Micklewright J, Nolan B (2013) The Great Recession and the distribution of household income, Oxford: Oxford University Press

  • Koos S, Vihalemm T, Keller M (2017) Coping with Crises: Consumption and Social Resilience on Markets. Int J Consum Stud 41:363–370

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin R, Sunley P (2015) On the notion of regional economic resilience: conceptualization and explanation. J Econ Geogr 15:1–42

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin R, Sunley P, Tyler P (2015) Local growth evolutions: recession, resilience and recovery. Camb J Reg Econ Soc 8:141–148

    Google Scholar 

  • Masik G, Rzyski S (2014) Resilience of Pomorskie region to economic crisis. Bulletin of Geopgraphy: Socio-Economic Series 25:129–141

    Google Scholar 

  • Miniaci R, Weber G (1999) The Italian Recession of 1993: Aggregate Implications of Microeconomic Evidence. Rev Econ Stat 81(2):237–249

    Google Scholar 

  • Modica M, Reggiani A (2015) Spatial Economic Resilience: Overview and Perspectives. Netw Spat Econ 15:211–233

    Google Scholar 

  • Nicolau JL, Más F (2005) Stochastic modeling: a three-stage tourist choice process. Ann Tour Res 32(1):49–69

    Google Scholar 

  • Östh J, Reggiani A, Nijkamp P (2018) Resilience and accessibility to Swedish and Dutch Municipalities. Transportation. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11116-017-9854-3

  • Palaskas T, Psycharis Y, Rovolis A, Stoforos C (2015) The asymmetrical impact of the economic crisis on unemployment and welfare in Greek urban economies. J Econ Geogr 15:973–1007

    Google Scholar 

  • Papatheodorou A, Rosselló J, Xiao H (2010) Global Economic Crisis and Tourism: Consequences and Perspectives. J Travel Res 49(1):39–45

    Google Scholar 

  • Pellegrini G (2002) Proximity, Polarization, and Local Labor Market Performances. Netw Spat Econ 2:151–173

    Google Scholar 

  • Percoco M (2004) Infrastructure and Economic Efficiency in Italian Regions. Netw Spat Econ 4:361–378

    Google Scholar 

  • Reggiani A, De Graaff T, Nijkamp P (2002) Resilience: an evolutionary approach to spatial economic systems. Netw Spat Econ 2:211–229

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodano ML, Rondinelli C (2014) The Italian Household Consumption: A Comparison Among Recessions. Politica Economica 2(3):203–234

    Google Scholar 

  • Smeral E (2009) The Impact of the Financial and Economic Crisis on European Tourism. J Travel Res 48(1):3–13

    Google Scholar 

  • Smeral E (2010) Impacts of the World Recession and Economic Crisis on Tourism: Forecasts and Potential Risks. J Travel Res 49:31–38

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors wish to thank Terry Friesz, Aura Reggiani and three anonymous referees for their constructive comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Cristina Bernini.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1: The Zero-Expenditure Approach to the Demand Model

Tourism is a censored good, that is, not all individuals participate in the tourism market. Consequently, the model in Eq. (2) should be revisited to account for a large proportion of observations with a value of tourism expenditure equal to zero (i.e., a censored variable). In the applied model analysis, we adopt the Cragg approach to the zero-expenditure model (Cragg 1971) because of its flexibility. The ‘double-hurdle’ model assumes that (i) an individual has to desire a positive amount of goods or services (first hurdle: the participation decision), and (ii) there must be favorable circumstances for a positive expenditure to occur (second hurdle: the consumption decision). Formally, our approach integrates the probit model to determine the probability of y* > 0 and the truncated normal model for given positive values of y*, as follows:participation decision:

$$ {d}_i^{\ast }={\alpha}^{\prime }{z}_i+{v}_i,\mathrm{where}\ {v}_i\to N\left(0,1\right) $$
(5)
$$ {d}_i=\left\{\begin{array}{cc}1& \mathrm{if}\ {d}_i^{\ast }>0\\ {}0& \mathrm{otherwise},\end{array}\right. $$
(6)

and consumption decision:

$$ {y}_i^{\ast }={\upbeta}^{\prime }{x}_i+{u}_i,\mathrm{where}\ {u}_i\to N\left(0,{\upsigma}^2\right) $$
(7)
$$ {y}_i=\left\{\begin{array}{cc}{y}_i^{\ast }& \mathrm{if}\ {d}_i=1\ \mathrm{and}\ {y}_i^{\ast }>0\\ {}0& \mathrm{otherwise},\end{array}\right. $$
(8)

where x and z are a different set of variables affecting the two decision stages, while the variables are assumed to be uncorrelated with their respective error terms; \( {d}_i^{\ast } \) is a latent variable that denotes binary censoring and \( {y}_i^{\ast } \) the unobserved latent value of expenditure. Eq. (8) indicates that the observed expenditure yi is zero, either when there is censoring at zero (\( {y}_i^{\ast}\le 0 \)) or when there is faulty reporting, due to some random circumstance. In other words, a positive level of tourism consumption (\( {y}_i={y}_i^{\ast } \)) is observed only if the individual is a potential tourist (di = 1) and actually consumes tourism services (\( {y}_i^{\ast }>0 \)).

An interesting feature of the Cragg model is that different sets of determinants affect the two hurdles. Separating the two decision stages is particularly relevant in modeling tourism consumption, since the decision to travel can be assumed to be mainly related to social factors, while the decision about how much to spend on a holiday depends on individual budget constraints.Footnote 10

Appendix 2: Data Description and Cohort Definition

The empirical analysis has been performed on the data from the Households Budget Survey (HBF), carried out by the Italian Office of Statistics (ISTAT). A sample of 400,473 households was collected over the period 1997 to 2013. With regard to tourism, HBF observes the monthly total amount of expenditure of the household on trips for personal purposes. Following international standards, HBF records expenditure, both for national and international trips on holidays, leisure and recreation, visiting friends and relatives, health treatment, religious activity and pilgrimages, etc. The survey does not provide information about the reason for the trip, so it is impossible to investigate how it affects tourism expenditure. We use ‘tourism expenditure’ below to refer to expenditure on trips for personal purposes. The respondent is a member of the household who reports the tourism expenditure of all members of the family. The survey does not provide information about the number of household members making a trip; but it does indicate if Italian families travel abroad or in the country and if they report an expenditure other than zero. Data on expenditure is supplemented by a rich set of economic, demographic, and sociological variables on Italian households. The HBF survey is performed every year and involves a random sample of the population. A pool of time series of cross sectional observations can thus be set up and groups of households can be followed over time by means of cohort techniques (Deaton 1985). The cohorts have been identified by using the age of the head of the household.

Following Attanasio and Weber (1994), Browning et al. (1985) and Deaton (1985), we group households on the basis of the age of the head of the household, using five-year age band cohorts, and we track the cohorts over time. The age of each household head (i.e. “a”) is defined as the mid-range age of the age-classFootnote 11 which the household head belongs to, while cohort “c” is defined as c = t - a, where “t” is the year in which the household was interviewed. In Table 7, the definition of cohorts, the head of the household’s age in the first and last year of observation, and the size of the cohorts are reported.

Table 7 Cohort Definition

Appendix 3: Model Estimates

Table 8 Participation and Consumption functions estimates

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bernini, C., Cracolici, M.F. & Nijkamp, P. Micro and Macro Resilience Measures of an Economic Crisis. Netw Spat Econ 20, 47–71 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11067-019-09470-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11067-019-09470-9

Keywords

JEL code

Navigation