1 Introduction

This study investigates the economic consequences of two opposing legal principles that may be applied by legislators to determine the priority rights of various parties when a business becomes insolvent. Our focus is on a case involving advance purchases, where an item has been paid for but due to the seller’s bankruptcy is not delivered. In such cases, the firm’s (or, seller’s) bankruptcy proceedings begin before they make the delivery, thus hindering the delivery despite the customer having already paid the agreed-upon price while the seller was still solvent. In this situation, the legislators must determine the party that takes priority over the undelivered item—the seller’s creditor(s) or the customer. The legal variant of this problem has been debated among lawyers within different jurisdictions.

Under the contract principle (also called the consensus principle), the buyer is given priority over the seller’s other creditors.Footnote 1 Since there is a valid contract, and provided the item is specified, the bankruptcy estate must give the buyer priority for the item. In this case, the item is not considered part of the bankruptcy estate. Conversely, under the ‘traditio’ principle (also called the delivery principle) the buyer is protected only if the delivery has already happened.Footnote 2 If the delivery has not been made, the estate will most likely fulfil the contract since the estate usually prefers to get the full price in exchange.Footnote 3 In cases where the delivery has not been made but the buyer has already paid (all or part of the price), the bankruptcy estate may refuse to deliver the item, and rather re-sell it. In this situation, it is possible for the original buyer to re-purchase the item, but she would have to pay once again. This is because the bankruptcy estate does not have to repay the prepayment since the recovery claim for the prepayment is treated as any other credit claim. Since the buyer is not among the prioritised creditors, she (or he) will, at most, receive a dividend of her (first) payment.

This study is framing the problem described above as a problem of competing claims for priority. The main question raised in this study queries whether policymakers should favour the principle that prioritises buyers with valid contracts for the undelivered items or the principle that treats such buyers as equal to other unsecured creditors. These two principles have been adopted differently in various jurisdictions; see Sect. 2, and lawyers and policymakers require that the answer to the question of which principle should be favoured be based on economic reasons.Footnote 4

An advanced purchase (a forward transaction), where the price at which the product will be sold is an outcome of a bargaining process between the buyer and the seller, requires prior agreement between these parties. Such transactions are common among solvent businesses. However, if a company becomes insolvent after such a contract is made but before the product is delivered, bankruptcy laws take effect and claims to the undelivered product become an issue. Our model focuses on the ex ante decision-making behaviour of creditors, buyers, and investors in such an occurrence. We adhere to the creditor’s bargaining theory (Jackson 1982; Baird and Jackson 1984; Baird 2017; Casey 2019) and demonstrate how a fictive change in an ex post legal principle will be priced and affect the ex ante bargaining of the different actors with competing claims (Bebchcuk and Fried 1996). We consider that the actors with stronger claims under the bankruptcy will be charged ex-ante fees by other claimholders. There are numerous empirical observations of such ‘adjusting’ creditors. For instance, a new priority law was introduced in Finland in 1993, through which, secured creditors who, before the law changed had a floating charge that gave them 100% priority on their collateral, now enjoyed partial priority. The reduced secured creditor’s priority was not found to lead to an increase in the post-bankruptcy value to be distributed among the creditors; neither did it reduce the cost of bankruptcy [Bergström et al. (2004), compare with Cerqueiro et al. (2016), for the later Swedish example.] Another example is the study by Kale and Shahrur (2007), which shows a significant negative relationship between a firm’s debt level and its relationship-specific investments by customers and suppliers. A low debt level acts as a commitment mechanism that induces suppliers and customers to adjust and undertake relationship investments. Similarly, studying the auctions of used cars, Hortacsu et al. (2013) find that customers discounted the price of the cars sold by distressed firms and the future expected loss of valued ‘amenities’ reduced the consumer´s willingness to pay. These examples show that it is not only professional creditors like banks that adjust to how insolvent company assets will be distributed; even so-called non-adjusting, or involuntary creditors (Baird and Jackson 1984; Bebchcuk and Fried 1996), change their a priori valuations.

We differ from the vast economic literature on value distribution and bankruptcy in that they mainly focus on how well different bankruptcy systems facilitate the transfer of assets to their most productive uses (e.g. Hotchkiss 1995; Maksimovics and Phillips 1998; Hotchkiss et al. 2007; Bernstein et al. 2018). These empirical economic studies that compare different legal regimes tend to be limited to comparisons between US Chapter 11 and Chapter 7 experiences. For example, Pulvino (1998) shows that the financial conditions of an airline determine the price the airline receives when selling aircrafts, and this reflects the risk that, during bankruptcy procedures, the airline’s assets may end up at low-value buyers (e.g. Schleifer and Vishny 1992). Similar to the literature on adjusting creditors, Pulvino suggests that his results may have effects on financial leverage and the cost of capital. In a later study, Pulvino (1999) finds that transaction prices are the same in Chapter 11 and Chapter 7 bankruptcies. A related measurement issue that arises from this relates to how the costs of financial distress are measured. Following Altman (1984, 1993), the practice is to measure financial distress as the difference between the pre-distress market value of a firm minus its post-bankruptcy value minus the gross value recovered by the claimholder (see also Franks and Torous 1994; Branch 2002; Bris et al. 2006). Here, we highlight the importance of interpreting the performance of a legal system correctly (see Sect. 2.3). For instance, if one looks at the advance prices paid in the two systems and finds that the contract regime prices for the advance purchases are higher than those in the traditio regime, it would be erroneous to conclude that the contract regime is economically more profitable to the seller using a proper measure. We show that the higher advance price in the contract regime is compensated for by the reduced pre-bankruptcy risk and, hence, a reduced cost of credit. Looking at only one or the other would be misleading. The more relevant matter is how the priority regime (contract or traditio) affects the decision to invest, the generation of total economic surplus, and its distribution.

When it comes to earlier legal research on which principle should be favoured, we refer to Sect. 2 of this paper. Within the issue of legal systematics, there are legal studies on which principle is the better choice. In the joint research project for the Draft Common Frame of Reference (DCFR, edited by von Bar and Clive 2010), the Study Group on a European Civil Code had such an ambitionFootnote 5 and chose the traditio regime.Footnote 6 Interestingly, part of their method was to vote among some of the researchers.Footnote 7 This is not entirely remarkable since the issue was also about a central feature of the entire system of the regulation. Some lawyers consider the systematic aspect of the issue to be the most important aspect.Footnote 8 In another legal and economic study concerning a jurisdiction that uses the traditio principle, it was found that the economic efficiency of traditio could be questioned, although the researcher found no suitable way to empirically measure the effects (Henriksson 2009, compare Henriksson 2015). For the same jurisdiction, numerous legal studies on which principle is superior also exist.Footnote 9

Our results show that if the priority regimes are known a priori, then the market will price each regime differently and in a way that makes the players indifferent about the regimes. Thus, even though the price of credits may differ between the two regimes, the ex-ante expected surplus would be the same. The pricing differences that occur balance the additional surplus that one gets from a favourable post-bankruptcy priority regime, by reducing the surplus that would have been obtained had a bankruptcy not occurred.

The reminder of this paper is structured as follows. Section 2 explains the legal context and intrigue of the problem under study from a lawyer’s perspective. Section 3 develops the study’s basic economic model and the resolution thereof for each of the two priority regimes. Section 4 discusses the economic implications of each regime for variables like interest rate and the advance price, and Sect. 5 concludes the study.

2 Legal context and lawyers’ treatment of the problem

The research question in this article is limited to the choice of principle for buyer priority. It should be noted that, in spite of economic efficiency being a major concern and a cause for argumentation, the perspective adopted for this question is not in all aspects the common perspective among lawyers. There are many available legal studies that would help us explore the legal framework of the question, especially when examining various jurisprudences concerning specific jurisdictions.Footnote 10 However, taking this route would deviate the study from its primary objective, leading it to several research questions related to some of the difficulties of conducting a comparative legal study. Our intention is not to deal with those research questions.Footnote 11 We do, however, need to explain the legal context of this problem in general terms and discuss the manner in which lawyers treat the issue of competing claims for priority over an insolvent seller’s assets. To make these explanations comprehensible, we start by pointing out the functions of the two principles in a way that reflects the legal analysis behind our perspective.

2.1 Functions of the principles in the context of nearby regulation

The principles of traditio and contract form the first set of rules that lawyers use to determine whether buyers should be given priority in a business’ insolvency. The second set of rules at lawyers’ disposal in such matters includes those concerning the invalidity of simulated contracts. In all jurisdictions, there are rules providing for the invalidity of contracts and for pretended and fraudulently constructed transactions to be disregarded. For example, when a debtor, together with someone claimed to be the ‘buyer’, fraudulently purports that an asset was ‘sold’ prior to the insolvency proceedings, such a ‘transaction’ is, in one way or the other, ineffective against the other creditors.Footnote 12 There needs to be a true transaction to get priority before the creditors. The third set of rules regulates the possibilities for the recovery of transactions that were not made on market terms. The ‘sale’ of a piece of property at a low price to the seller’s close associates or to others that the seller wishes to favour over other creditors, can be reversed or adjusted based on these rules. The Roman law institute, Actio Pauliana, has influenced our later legal systems.Footnote 13

The functions of the above-mentioned sets of rules in deciding the priority of each party are different. In principle, they address different aspects, although they also partly overlap. Looking at the fundamental functions, the rules on the contractual invalidity of simulated contracts can be used when the legitimacy of a transaction is questionable. The rules of transaction recovery address transactions that are real but not made on market terms. In comparison, traditio and contract principles fundamentally address valid transactions made according to market terms, but create inequality amongst the collective of creditors in that the buyer is seen as one of them, since it is mainly the buyers—who have made advance payments—who are affected by these principles.

It should be noted that both traditio and contract principles serve the function of creating equality among creditors. The difference between the two principles concerns the point in time when priority is granted. With the traditio principle, priority is granted at delivery. In contrast, with the contract principle, priority is granted at the point when the sold asset is specified for the buyer, which may occur at an earlier point than the delivery, and in case of sale of a specific asset is already at the agreement on the contract. Therefore, in practice, the choice between contract and traditio is not a choice of whether the regulation of priority should have an additional rule, in addition to simulation and recovery rules, but an inevitable choice of when the buyer should reach priority.

In addition to the above-described function, it is relevant to note that the traditio principle but not the contract principle, overlaps the functions of the rules of simulation and recovery. If a transaction does not fulfil the traditio requirement, it is not necessary to deal with the evidence on the grounds of simulation or recovery. In some of the debates and legal analyses around the world, this function is seen as the primary function of traditio, while the issue of equality is not even part of the picture.Footnote 14 Another indirect function of the traditio requirement is based on the assumption that the risk for debtors (sellers) becoming over-indebted is less if their buyers have an incentive to not leave the goods with the seller. This is because it is assumed that leaving the goods with the seller gives the seller a chance to use the goods to get liquidity through another sale or as security for credit.Footnote 15 In addition, there are differences in the sanctions that make traditio preferable for the creditors, as compared to recovery.

2.2 Relevance and irrelevance of ownership and transfer of ownership

One reason behind many lawyers having differing perspectives, both amongst themselves and from ours in this study, is that they make a connection between when a buyer obtains priority against the seller´s creditors and the systemic structure of the property law regulations in their jurisdictions.Footnote 16 Thus, the question of priority for buyers, in several cases, becomes a question of the transfer of ownership.Footnote 17 This is a question connected to several other possible conflicts concerning competing claims and the circumstances around contractual agreements, delivery, etc. von Bar and Clive (2010) writes,

In most European countries there are rules defining the right of ownership … and rules defining a particular moment when this right of ownership passes from the transferor (owner) to the transferee. At this moment all ‘aspects’ related to the right of ownership as defined, like the owner’s right to recover possession of the property from another person even if that other person is insolvent (i.e. protection as against that other person’s general creditors). (pp. 4379–4380)

The idea of a unitary starting point for how to resolve all these conflicts affects the perspective, both consciously and subconsciously.Footnote 18 Even in jurisdictions that do not use a system that considers the transfer of ownership as the starting point, the lawyers’ thinking has been affected by notions of ownership.Footnote 19 Through different jurisdictions, it is possible to find variations of the argument that buyers who do not get what they bought are treated unfairly.Footnote 20 As such, the issue is put in terms of the buyers’ possibilities to obtain ‘protection’ against the other creditors.Footnote 21 Arguments for taking this perspective suggest that it is ‘natural’ and even ‘fair’ that a buyer receives the item they purchased.Footnote 22 The politically idea that ‘ownership’ is a ‘right’ that must be respected is, in this way, used in what can be seen as out of context. von Bar and Clive (2010) state that,

Consensual model coincides with “natural expectations” of the parties, etc. It is sometimes stated that ordinary people—or ordinary business people—consider it “natural” that a buyer (or other transferee) acquires a right to separate the (specific) goods upon concluding the contract for sale. (p. 4389)

Unsurprisingly, these arguments for ownership, rights, and fairness can be easily reversed. Lawyers who favour the traditio principle argue that a prepaying buyer is not significantly different from other creditors who have given the debtor credit. Therefore, it is ‘fair’ that the buyer should not be treated better than other creditors in accordance with the principle of equal payment. von Bar and Clive (2010) describe this view, stating that,

[A] transferee of specific goods is a general creditor like others. Unless ownership has already passed under a contractual agreement for an immediate transfer or a rule of law to this effect, a transferee of specific goods who has concluded a contract for sale but has not yet taken delivery and against whom, therefore, the transferor is simply obliged to transfer the ownership, is nothing but a general creditor of the transferor. (p. 4396)

We will make some comments on these themes in the following sections, which is important also on a terminological level. In this section, we only elaborate our research question. We have chosen this question on buyer priority since priority is the relevant economic function of the choice between traditio and contract. Therefore, the focus of this study is the issue of priority. In this context, ownership is just a linking concept and the transfer of ownership is a superstructureFootnote 23; here, these two are not the real issue.Footnote 24 In sum, we have singled out one issue: the preferred choice of principle in determining the prioritisation of buyers over an insolvent seller’s other creditors.Footnote 25

The fact that we have singled out one issue does not mean that we see the systemic aspects as irrelevant. On the contrary, the relevance of these aspects is acknowledged, particular given that different solutions form a system of solutions in different jurisdictions. In view of such systems and their overall effects, it is therefore possible that the contract principle is a more effective solution in one jurisdiction, while traditio is more effective in another. What we investigate, however, is whether policymakers should favour one principle over another with regard to priority for buyers. Note that it is the policymakers we are investigating, and that this can be a legislator or body in a position to decide the common terms of a specific market. In most jurisdictions with a traditio principle, it is possible to use standard contracts that depart from the traditio requirement and instead use the requirement of specificity used under the contract principle. It is even possible for two parties to individually depart from traditio when it suits the situation.Footnote 26

2.3 Dissent among lawyers’ perspectives on priority—lawyers created reality

The disagreement between lawyers on this matter does not imply their disinterest in the economic effects of the regulation. On the contrary, economic efficiency has been a major concern and an evident cause for argumentation. In their debates, lawyers have made different assumptions to promote one principle over the other, as well as advocated for how strictly the respective principles should be used. Such argumentation and the assumptions behind it can be found in several kinds of legal contexts, including in research, the reasoning of Supreme Court Judges, and proposals to change regulation.Footnote 27

Those who prefer traditio claim that this principle is necessary to discourage fraud. Such fraud is the result of asymmetric information where the manager of a company learns of the possibilities of a bankruptcy before the other stakeholders, such as the company’s creditors. In such a case, the debtors may try to transfer value from the company to their friends and preferred business relations before going bankrupt by committing to under-priced deliveries. In particular, these lawyers contend that the contract principle may be used by a debtor claiming that specific assets have already been sold when creditors arrive in the event of a bankruptcy. The traditio principle is assumed to lessen the level of this risk since the goods must be moved to the buyer in order to be safe from the seller’s creditors. This assumption is often retold among lawyers but seldom backed up, apart from using anecdotal experiences. The empirical evidence for this argument is scarce, but there is an odd example from the Netherlands dating back to 1936. That empirical study showed that in most districts of the Netherlands at that time, 50–90% of all judicial executions over corporeal movable assets proved unsuccessful because of prior transfers of ownership for security purposes, of which 90% were assumed to be simulated (Meijers 1936).Footnote 28

Among those who favour the contract principle, the assumptions may trigger concerns about international competition. Suppose a buyer could carry out an advance purchase (pay now for delivery later) from company \( A \) operating in a jurisdiction that follows the traditio principle, or from company \( B \) in a jurisdiction that follows the contract principle. If both companies have equal chances of going bankrupt, the consumer will prefer to buy from company \( B \) as it provides a greater assurance of delivery. This will make it more difficult for company \( A \) to attract advance purchases and, if this is an integral part of their business, reduces the ability of company \( A \) to compete with company \( B \) for buyers who can operate in either jurisdictions. Assumptions like this have been used as decisive arguments in the legislation process, such as in the Swedish law commission proposal SOU 2015:18, where a proposal was made that the Swedish traditio principle should be replaced with a contract principle. The assumption of the Swedish Inquiry is one that is not supported by an actual study. These assumptions are conveyed in SOU 2015:18, stating that,

In many comparable countries, the law of property is based on a contractual principle of some kind … For international manufacturing purchases, agreements regularly prescribe that manufactured products become the buyer’s property as soon as they are individualised. When a Swedish company sells according to these conditions, the traditio requirement means that the condition of ownership becomes ineffective. In such a situation, the buyer may require more extensive financial guarantees or ultimately chooses a seller from another country than Sweden, (p. 92).

Among jurists’ conceptions, there are direct inaccuracies as well. One example is the claim that the traditio requirement results in transaction costs for all transactions.Footnote 29 Thus, lawyers have failed to exclude, in transaction cost terms, those transactions where the parties, for reasons other than the traditio requirement, carry out delivery at the time of purchase anyway. In the same way, lawyers have failed to consider that it is probably mainly prepaying buyers who incur losses because of the traditio requirement.Footnote 30 Lawyers have claimed that all buyers are affected by the traditio requirement, even though a bankruptcy trustee has significant reason (such as transaction costs) to want to fulfil an agreed sale at market price.

Lawyers from jurisdictions with fairly similar societies use different conceptions of economic conditions to justify the principle they use themselves. For example, the traditio principle can, in one jurisdiction, be motivated primarily by the risk of pretended and fraudulent transactions, while the argument that property in the debtor’s possession gives the appearance of false wealth is considered outdated. At the same time, it is possible to find that other jurisdictions consider such false wealth viable, while the risk of pretended and fraudulent transactions is seen as small and is scarcely mentioned.Footnote 31

Although there are numerous other examples that could be mentioned regarding how lawyers justify their perspectives, these are not the focus of this article; but rather, this subsection simply explains part of the reason our research question is relevant. However, it is worth noting that the variations in lawyers’ assumptions seem to follow legal traditions rather than differences in the economic conditions of our societies. This makes an interesting study in itself, and one aspect that can be examined here is the economic assumptions that lawyers in a specific legal tradition make. This constitutes a special phenomenon that has been aptly called the lawyer-created reality.Footnote 32 However, this theme is beyond the scope of this study.Footnote 33

2.4 Overview of the differences in the choices of principle

To further illustrate why the choice of principle is an interesting issue, we present an overview of the principles different jurisdictions use. It is important to note that there are dissimilarities between the different traditio principles and contract principles. For example, a contract principle may give precedence to one party based on the conclusion of the agreement or the fact that the buyer or seller, in addition to entering into a contract, also acted in a certain manner.Footnote 34 Similarly, the traditio principle has variations. For example, this principle can impose an absolute requirement that can only be replaced by a registration measure; but it can also be dispositive so that buyers and sellers can agree on the seller holding the purchased item on behalf of the buyer after the purchase.Footnote 35 This kind of agreement can be instituted under various terms and may describe the point in time at which the buyer should be prioritised over the seller’s other creditors.Footnote 36 Regimes that allow this diversion from traditio may lead to difficulties in interpreting what the parties have agreed upon, and depending on how these aspects are treated in the regime, it may be questionable whether such a regime should be seen as a traditio or contract regime.Footnote 37 Table 1 gives the basic principles followed by different countries. Since there are many variations and nuances in the different regimes, the table should be regarded as a rough simplification, indicating whether a legal system for a sale of goods applies a contract principle or requires delivery, i.e. traditio.

Table 1 Regimes followed by different countries

If we assume that the above list gives us reliable information and a rough picture of how various jurisdictions apply the principles, we can draw the conclusion that there is no clear overweight for any of the two principles.Footnote 38 We can also conclude that neighbouring countries with similar circumstances have chosen different regimes.

Since our ambition is to show a general difference between contract and traditio, we begin with simplifications; that is, we consider the contract principle to require a contract and that the object be specified, and regard the traditio principle as requiring an agreement and a delivery, i.e. that the buyer has taken possession of the purchased item.

3 The model

3.1 Developing the model

There are many reasons for buying things in ‘advance’. One such reason is when a seller produces a product specifically for one buyer. Because the product is being customised for that particular buyer (e.g. based on technical specifications that are unique to the prospective buyer), two issues arise. First, it is difficult to anticipate the market price for such a product. Second, it is less costly to initiate the customisation of the product early on in the production process.

Our model starts with an uncertain project that requires an investment of \( I > 0 \) to get started. There are two investors, an equity owner, and a creditor (bank). The bank invests a loan amount \( L \) while the equity owner invests \( A \equiv I - L \). We will assume that the risk-free interest rate on the loan is zero and the bank operates in a competitive market. For its loan \( L \), the bank has a debt claim of \( D \), payable when the project return is realised. In its usual course, the project yields a return \( R \) if it is successfully completed and return \( r \) if it is unsuccessful,\( r \) where \( R > r \ge 0 \). The project succeeds with probability \( p \) and fails with probability \( \left( {1 - p} \right) \). The uncertainty in the project returns is due to the uncertain market conditions that will prevail in Stage 2. If market conditions are good, the project realises the higher return \( R \); otherwise, it returns a value of \( r \). The reality of the business’s limited liability introduces bankruptcy possibilities, as the bank may not be fully repaid when the project fails. Of course, when the project succeeds there is enough to pay the bank.

Additionally, there is a possibility that after the project commences, and before it concludes, an advance buyer will ask for a product that entails a cost \( m > 0 \), for which the buyer is willing to pay an advance price \( v \ge m, \) an amount payable before the realisation of the project. This happens with probability \( q, 1 \ge q > 0 \). The possible presence of the advance buyer makes the bankruptcy process slightly complicated if the firm enters bankruptcy before the product is delivered to the buyer. There are now two prior claimants at the end of the project, the bank and the advance buyer.Footnote 39 Thus, this study’s question is, ‘should the advance price \( v \) be returned (or the product be delivered) to the advance buyer even if the bank (lender) is not fully repaid?’

Figure 1 gives the timeline or sequence of events in the model. In Stage 0, the firm is set up with a limited liability debt contract. In Stage 1, an advance buyer may, or may not, appear. In Stage 2, the project realisation happens.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Timeline

The customised product has a market value \( v^{\prime} \) at the end of the project, but is valued at \( v^{\prime\prime} \ge v^{\prime} \) by the advance buyer. Since the product is customised to a specific buyer, the latter’s valuation is more than what the average (market) buyer is willing to pay for it.

Consider a car company selling cars in two popular colours, both at the cost \( v^{\prime} \). Consider also that a customer wants a third colour, which she particularly prefers, but the company does not offer that colour because its cost is higher than what the market is willing to pay. If the car company uses this third colour on some of its cars, it would have to sell all its cars at the same price, despite the ones in the third colour costing the company more to produce. In this example, not only is the customer who wants the rare colour willing to bear the cost of that colour, but she may actually be willing to pay a premium price (\( v^{\prime\prime} \)) for it.

Alternatively, consider a company that produces a good that is used as an input in the production of many other goods. The advance buyer in this case may be a producer requiring a unique specification for this intermediate good, given the design of her final product. Since this intermediate product would have little (sold as scrap) or no market value, its market value \( v^{\prime} \) would be low, but its value to the advance buyer (\( v^{\prime\prime}) \) would be high. Indeed, this also explains why the supplier of the advance purchase would insist on a commitment by the buyer before producing such a customised product.

Should the project be successful, the market value \( v^{\prime} \) would become irrelevant since the lender would be fully repaid. The customised product would go to the advance buyer and not put on the market. However, should the project fail and the bank has the first claim, then, if need be, the bank could put the advance buyer’s product on the market and collect a value of \( v^{\prime} \). The market condition does not affect the values of \( v \) and \( m \) as they are determined in Stage 1, before the uncertainty is resolved (in Stage 2).

In such situations, it is important to understand the role played by the advance buyer. Suppose the project involves the production of cars. The advance buyer may want a customised car, where the customisation must happen during the process of production.Footnote 40 This can happen only if the buyer of this customised product makes the commitment to buy it before the completion of the project. This customisation would be an additional cost \( m \) in the project, and so the final return would be reduced by \( m \). On the other hand, because the product is customised, its value to the advance buyer would be \( v^{\prime\prime} \ge v^{\prime} \). Should the project succeed, the value in the project available to the investors would be \( R - m + v \).Footnote 41 Should the project fail, the value available in the project to pay the bank would be \( r - m + v \) if the product has to be delivered to the advance buyer. If, however, the bank has the first claim on the undelivered product, the amount available to them would be \( r - m + v + v^{\prime} \). We assume that at Stage 0, both the bank and equity owner know that, with probability \( q, \) an advance buyer may appear in Stage 1.

Let (superscript) \( C \) denote the contract regime, through which the advance buyer has the first claim on the undelivered product during bankruptcy, and (superscript) \( T \) denote the traditio regime, through which the bank has the first claim on all the assets (including the undelivered product). Let \( D^{j} \), \( j = C,T \) be the debt claim of the bank under priority regime \( j \). Under \( C \), the advance buyer pays an advance price \( v^{C} \) to obtain a surplus of \( v^{\prime\prime} - v^{C} \), where \( v^{\prime\prime} \) is the advance buyer’s valuation of the customised product. As explained before, \( v^{\prime\prime} \ge v^{\prime} \) since the product is customised to the advance buyer’s preferences and not the general market’s preference. If we are in the contract regime, then the advance buyer’s surplus, \( \varOmega^{C} \) is non-stochastic and \( \varOmega^{C} = v^{\prime\prime} - v^{C} \).

3.2 Solving the model

3.2.1 The contract regime

There are two variables, \( v^{j} \) and \( D^{j} \), to solve in each regime \( j \), \( j = C,T \). Let us consider the contract regime first. The advance buyer is contracting for a product that is customised to her specification for a value \( v^{\prime\prime} \) that she gets from the customisation. This customisation comes at a cost \( m \), generating a total surplus \( v^{\prime\prime} - m \). This surplus will have to be distributed between the project and the advance buyer. The distribution has to be decided through a bargaining process between the advance buyer and the decision-maker in the project, who, in our case, is the entrepreneur or the equity owner. However, we will not investigate the bargaining process between the two in this study, but merely solve for it. One possible way to solve for the outcome of the bargaining game is to assume that the two parties go through a Nash bargaining process. In that case, the proportion of the surplus going to each party depends on their relative bargaining strength. We will take that as a given and say that \( v^{C} \) is the advance price that generates the Nash bargaining solution. Here, the advance buyer receives the surplus \( v^{\prime\prime} - v^{C} \) and the project receives \( v^{C} - m \).

We will denote the net surplus of the equity owner, bank, and advance buyer in each regime \( j \) to be \( \varPi^{j} \), \( \varGamma^{j} \),and \( \varOmega^{j} \), respectively, where \( j = C,T \).

Result 1

Let \( v^{C} \) be the price paid by the advance buyer, where \( v^{C} \) is the outcome of the Nash bargaining process between the advance buyer and the project. Then

$$ \varOmega^{C} = v^{\prime\prime} - v^{C} ,\varGamma^{C} = 0\,\,{\text{and}}\,\,\varPi^{C} = \left[ {pR + \left( {1 - p} \right)r - I} \right] + q\left( {v^{C} - m} \right) $$

(For proof, please see “Appendix”.)

The surplus in the system is distributed among the equity owner, bank, and the advance buyer. The bank is competitive, hence it cannot make a positive surplus. The surplus generated in the project without the advance buyer is \( \left[ {pR + \left( {1 - p} \right)r - I} \right] \) and the equity owner keeps all of it. The presence of the advance buyer generates an additional surplus \( v^{\prime\prime} - m \), which is divided between the equity owner and the advance buyer. This division is determined through Nash bargaining, which generates \( v^{C} \), giving the equity owner a surplus \( v^{C} - m \) and the advance buyer, surplus \( v^{\prime\prime} - v^{C} \). However, because the advance buyer appears with probability \( q \), the surplus going to the equity owner is probabilistic.

Result 2

Let \( v^{C} \) be the price paid by the advance buyer, where \( v^{C} \) is the outcome of the Nash bargaining process between the advance buyer and the project. Then

$$ D^{C} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} L \hfill & {{\text{if}}\,L \le r} \hfill \\ {\frac{{L - \left( {1 - p} \right)\left( {1 - q} \right)r}}{{p + \left( {1 - p} \right)q}}} \hfill & {{\text{if}}\,r < L \le r + (v^{C} - m)[p + \left( {1 - p} \right)q]} \hfill \\ {\frac{{L - \left( {1 - p} \right)\left( {1 - q} \right)r - \left( {1 - p} \right)q(r + v^{C} - m)}}{p}} \hfill & {{\text{if}}\,r + \left( {v^{C} - m} \right)\left[ {p + \left( {1 - p} \right)q} \right] < L \le I} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. $$
(1)

(For proof, please see “Appendix”.)

3.2.2 Traditio regime

In the traditio regime, unlike in the contract regime, the advance buyer is not sure of obtaining \( v^{\prime\prime} \) at the end of the project, thus her surplus is stochastic. This is because if the project fails, the undelivered product will belong to the bank, where the bank will have to be paid more than \( r - m + v^{T} \).

However, before calculating the advance buyer’s surplus in the traditio regime, we need to make an additional point. Whenever the bank sells the undelivered product on the market, the advance buyer should be the one buying it. If she does not buy it, the value she receives in Stage 2 is zero, making her net return negative as she had already paid \( v^{T} \) in Stage 1. On the other hand, if she buys it, she will receive a positive value \( v^{\prime\prime} - v^{\prime} \ge 0 \) in Stage 2 against the price she had already paid. Note that the price \( v^{T} \) is a sunk cost in Stage 2.

Under \( T \), there are two different situations to consider:

  1. (a)

    \( r - m + v^{T} \ge D^{T} \): In this case, though the project has failed, the value of \( v^{T} \) is sufficiently high so that the bank gets fully paid and the advance buyer receives her full value \( v^{\prime\prime} \) (or, a net surplus of \( v^{\prime\prime} - v^{T} \)).

  2. (b)

    \( r - m + v^{T} < D^{T} \): Here the bank will lay claim to the undelivered product and sell it at \( v^{\prime} \). This will increase the value in the project to \( r - m + v^{T} + v^{\prime} \). If this is greater than \( D^{T} \), the bank will receive \( D^{T} \) and the advance buyer will receive the remainder, which is equal to \( r - m + v^{T} + v^{\prime} - D^{T} \).Footnote 42 If, on the other hand, \( r - m + v^{T} + v^{\prime} < D^{T} \), there will be no remainder for the advance buyer. To receive her customised product when the company is bankrupt, the advance buyer has to pay \( v^{\prime} \) which, as argued before, she does.

Putting these together, the advance buyer pays \( min\left[ {v^{\prime}, max\left\{ {r - m + v^{T} - D^{T} ,0} \right\}} \right] \) to obtain a Stage 2 value equal to

$$ [v^{\prime\prime} - min\left[ {v^{\prime}, max\left\{ {D^{T} - \left( {r - m + v^{T} } \right),0} \right\}} \right] $$

If \( r - m + v^{T} \ge D^{T} \), then \( max\left\{ {D^{T} - \left( {r - m + v^{T} } \right),0} \right\} = 0 \) and \( \hbox{min} \left\{ {v^{\prime},0} \right\} = 0 \), giving a Stage 2 value equal to \( v^{\prime\prime} \). If, on the other hand, \( r - m + v^{T} < D^{T} \), the bank lays claim to the undelivered product, which can be bought by the advance buyer with an additional amount that equals the shortfall of \( r - m + v^{T} \) from \( D^{T} \) but not more than \( v^{\prime}, \) which is the maximum that can be obtained in the market place for the customised product, the Stage 2 value received by the advance buyer will be less than \( v^{\prime\prime} \) but no less than \( v^{\prime\prime} - v^{\prime} \). Of course, all of this may only happen if the project fails; otherwise, the advance buyer receives the full value \( v^{\prime\prime} \) in Stage 2. Thus, we can write the traditio regime surplus of the advance buyer as

$$ \varOmega^{T} = pv^{\prime\prime} + \left( {1 - p} \right)\left[ {v^{\prime\prime} - min\left[ {v^{\prime}, max\left\{ {D^{T} - \left( {r - m + v^{T} } \right),0} \right\}} \right]} \right] - v^{T} . $$

There is no reason for the relative bargaining strength between the entrepreneur and the advance buyer to be different in the two regimes. Hence, compared to the contract regime, in the traditio regime, the bargaining strengths remain the same, but the distribution of the surplus is now dependent on the fact that, should the project fail, the lender/bank is a superior claimant compared to the advance buyer. This implies that the price the advance buyer will pay will be different from that in the contract regime. This follows from equating \( \varOmega^{C} \) to \( \varOmega^{T} \) (above). Setting \( \varOmega^{T} = \varOmega^{C} \), gives us

$$ \begin{aligned} v^{\prime\prime} - v^{C} & = pv^{\prime\prime} + \left( {1 - p} \right)[v^{\prime\prime} - min\left[ {v^{\prime}, max\left\{ {D^{T} - \left( {r - m + v^{T} } \right),0} \right\}} \right] - v^{T} \\ & = v^{\prime\prime} - \left( {1 - p} \right)\left[ {min\left[ {v^{\prime}, max\left\{ {D^{T} - \left( {r - m + v^{T} } \right),0} \right\}} \right]} \right] - v^{T} \\ \end{aligned} $$

On simplification, this yields

$$ v^{C} = v^{T} + \left( {1 - p} \right)\left[ {min\left[ {v^{\prime}, max\left\{ {D^{T} - \left( {r - m + v^{T} } \right),0} \right\}} \right]} \right] $$
(2)

Two things are immediate. First, \( v^{C} \ge v^{T} \). This is because the second expression on the right hand side of Eq. (2), \( \left( {1 - p} \right)\left[ {min\left[ {v^{\prime}, max\left\{ {D^{T} - \left( {r - m + v^{T} } \right),0} \right\}} \right]} \right] \) is always greater than or equal to zero. Second, \( v^{C} < v^{T} + v^{\prime} \). This is because the maximum value of the right hand side of Eq. (2) is \( v^{T} + \left( {1 - p} \right)v^{\prime} = v^{T} + v^{\prime} - pv^{\prime} < v^{T} + v^{\prime} \).

Result 3

Let \( v^{T} \) be the price paid by the advance buyer, where \( v^{T} \) is such that the Nash bargain process between the advance buyer and the project yields the same distribution, as that in the contract regime (with a surplus generated by the presence of the advance buyer). Then

$$ D^{T} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} L \hfill & {{\text{if}}\,L \le r} \hfill \\ {\frac{{L - \left( {1 - p} \right)\left( {1 - q} \right)r}}{{p + \left( {1 - p} \right)q}}} \hfill & {{\text{if}}\,r < L \le r + (v^{T} + v^{\prime } - m)[p + \left( {1 - p} \right)q]} \hfill \\ {\frac{{L - \left( {1 - p} \right)\left( {1 - q} \right)r - \left( {1 - p} \right)q(r + v^{T} + v^{\prime } - m)}}{p}} \hfill & {{\text{if}}\,r + \left( {v^{T} + v^{\prime } - m} \right)\left[ {p + \left( {1 - p} \right)q} \right] < L \le I} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. $$
(3)

(For proof, please see “Appendix”.)

Note that wherever we had \( v^{C} \) in Eq. (2), we also had \( v^{T} + v^{\prime}, \) for that is the amount available to the bank if the project fails and the advance buyer is present. By inspection, the proof is similar to that of Result 2 substituting \( v^{T} + v^{\prime} \) for \( v^{C} \).

The traditio regime’s return to the equity owner can be written as

$$ \begin{aligned} \varPi^{T} & = p\left( {1 - q} \right)\left[ {R - D^{T} } \right] + pq\left[ {R - D^{T} + v^{T} - m} \right] + \left( {1 - p} \right)\left( {1 - q} \right)max\left\{ {r - D^{T} ,0} \right\} \\ & \quad + \,q\left( {1 - p} \right)max\left\{ {r + v^{T} - m - D^{T} ,0} \right\} - A \\ & = p\left[ {R - D^{T} } \right] + pq\left( {v^{T} - m} \right) + \left( {1 - p} \right)\left( {1 - q} \right)max\left\{ {r - D^{T} ,0} \right\} \\ & \quad + \,q\left( {1 - p} \right)max\left\{ {r + v^{T} - m - D^{T} ,0} \right\} - \left( {I - L} \right) \\ \end{aligned} $$
(4)

Result 4

Let \( v^{T} \) be the price paid by the advance buyer, where \( v^{T} \) is such that the Nash bargain process between the advance buyer and the project yields the same distribution as that in the contract regime (with a surplus generated by the presence of the advance buyer). Then

$$ \varOmega^{C} = \varOmega^{T} ,\varGamma^{T} = \varGamma^{C} = 0\,\,{\text{and}}\,\,\varPi^{T} = \left[ {pR + \left( {1 - p} \right)r - I} \right] + q\left( {v^{C} - m} \right) = \varPi^{C} $$

(For proof, please see “Appendix”.)

This result states that under symmetric information, priority rules do not affect equilibrium surplus. First, observe that bank-lending occurs under a competitive market structure in both priority regimes. Therefore, in both cases, the parties do not realise a surplus, but rather, they break even. Second, since the advance buyer decides to buy (with probability \( q \)) after the contract regime has been chosen, her bargaining strength determines how much surplus she receives. The fact that \( v^{C} \) and \( v^{T} \) are endogenous allows the advance buyer to get an equal part of the surplus in both regimes. Third, the total surplus in the system, given by the project surplus plus that generated by the advance purchase, is independent of the priority regime and equals

$$ \left[ {pR + \left( {1 - p} \right)r - I} \right] + q\left( {v^{\prime\prime} - m} \right) $$

Since the bank receives a zero surplus and the advance buyer receives the same surplus in both regimes, the entrepreneur receives the same surplus in both regimes as well.

4 Implications

While the two priority regimes are equivalent in terms of the potential total surplus and its distribution among the agents, the equilibrium values of the variables in the system will vary according to the priority regime applied. In our view, the variables of special interest are \( D^{j} \) and \( v^{j} \), \( j = C,T \).

From our economic analysis, we know the bank’s default risk (as measured by the amount it can extract under bankruptcy) is lower in the contract regime than in the traditio regime. This happens in two ways. First, because \( v^{\prime\prime} + v^{\prime} > v^{C} \), the possibility of a default is lower in the traditio than in the contract regime.Footnote 43 Second, when the loan amount is such that a default could occur in both regimes, the recovery by the bank would be higher in traditio than in contract (again because \( v^{\prime\prime} + v^{\prime} > v^{C} \)). This means that for all loan amounts \( L \), the bank’s debt claim under traditio is no greater than that under contract and becomes strictly less as the loan amount increases. The debt claims are solved for in Eqs. (1) and (3) and illustrated in Fig. 2. Another way of looking at it is that the bank’s interest rate (measured as \( \left[ {\left( {D^{j} /L} \right) - 1} \right] \)) is (weakly) less under traditio than under contract, with the inequality being strict for loans that have a positive risk of default. Whatever additional value the bank receives in the traditio regime from an insolvent firm, it gives up in its collection through its interest rate for that firm.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Debt claims and loan amounts under the contract and traditio regime. From Eq. (2) in the text, \( v^{c} < v^{T} + v^{\prime } \) because the maximum value of the right hand side of Eq. (2) is \( v^{T} + \left( { 1- p} \right)v^{\prime } = v^{T} + v^{\prime } - pv^{\prime } < v^{T} + v^{\prime } \). Hence, \( r + \left( {v^{T} + v^{\prime } - m} \right)\left[ {p + \left( { 1- p} \right)q} \right] \, > r + \left( {v^{c} - m} \right)\left[ {p + \left( {1 - p} \right)q} \right]. \) The slopes are calculated from the expressions DC and DT given in Eqs. (1) and (3), respectively

The behaviour of the advance purchase price, on the other hand, is opposite to that of the interest rate on the loan. Without any risk of a loan default in either regime, we have \( v^{C} = v^{T} \). Whenever there is a risk of loan default, the traditio regime differs from the contract regime in that \( v^{C} > v^{T} \). This is illustrated in Fig. 3.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Advance product prices and loan amounts under contract and traditio regimes. From Eq. (2) in the text, \( v^{c} < v^{T} + v^{\prime } \) because the maximum value of the right hand side of Eq. (2) is \( v^{T} + \left( { 1- p} \right)v^{\prime } = v^{T} + v^{\prime } - pv^{\prime } < v^{T} + v^{\prime } \). Hence, \( r + \left( {v^{T} + v^{\prime } - m} \right)\left[ {p + \left( { 1- p} \right)q} \right] \, > r + \left( {v^{c} - m} \right)\left[ {p + \left( {1 - p} \right)q} \right]. \) Also, when we have \( L \ge r + \left( {v^{T} + v^{\prime } - m} \right)\left[ {p + \left( {1 - p} \right)q} \right], \) we know that \( D^{T} \ge \left( {r - m + v^{T} + v^{\prime } } \right) \) and this implies that \( \left[ {min[v^{\prime } ,max\{ D^{T} - (r - m + v^{T} ),0\} ]} \right] = v^{\prime } \) giving us \( v^{C} = v^{T} + (1 - p)v^{\prime } \)

Results 1 and 4 show that the priority regime, if known at the time of contracting, has no impact. This is because contracting parties internalise the economic consequences of the regime when taking ex ante decisions. However, as discussed in Sect. 2, some lawyers argue that, compared to the contract regime, the traditio regime prevents fraud more effectively. How do we consider this aspect of the lawyers’ argument in our economic analysis?

In our model, we have assumed that the advance buyer is an independent agent and not related in any way to the entrepreneur. In practice, however, the advance buyer could become endogenous to the system. It is reasonable to assume that the firm-insiders would have greater knowledge about project’s success probabilities. For instance, if the entrepreneur knows that a project will fail before it actually does, she may make a deal with a ‘related party’ to pose as an advance buyer. This buyer and the entrepreneur can settle on an official price \( v_{0} < v^{C} \), transfer \( v_{0} \) to the bank when the project fails, and share the surplus \( v^{C} - v_{0} \). Observe that this is not possible under the traditio regime because the bank has the first claim on all the value of a failed firm.

First, observe that in our model, the advance buyer is (often) contracting to buy a product that has a value higher than what the market is willing to pay. Consequently, this price is an outcome of the relative bargaining capabilities of the two parties—the project decision-maker and the buyer. These bargaining strengths are unobservable. Second, the project usually has information on impending insolvency before the creditor. In this situation, it is possible for the project to enter into a contract with related parties to sell products through the advance purchase mechanism.

‘Asset stripping’ under impending insolvency is well recognised in the literature. Indeed, legal codes in countries that otherwise follow the contract regime specifically enable bankruptcy officials to identify and nullify such agreements or cancel the suspect sales that may have been made prior to bankruptcy (see Sect. 2, and e.g. Mouial-Bassilana 2016). In reality, it is difficult to identify such agreements by simply looking at the price set in the agreement. For example, if \( v^{C} \ge v^{\prime} \), it is difficult for a bankruptcy official to claim fraud. Moreover, post customisation, the market value may actually be lower than \( m \) (the cost of customisation). On the other hand, if \( v^{0} > m \ge v^{\prime} \) and one is in a contract regime, it may be better for the creditor to honour the contract and collect the \( v^{0} \) even though the unobserved \( v^{C} \) could be well above \( v^{0} \). Under traditio, such a situation is irrelevant since \( v^{T} + v^{\prime} > v^{C} \) regardless of how they compare with \( m \).

5 Conclusion

This study investigated the economic consequences of two opposing regimes—traditio and contract—applied by legislators in different jurisdictions. Our results suggest that the two regimes are equivalent in terms of the net utilities enjoyed by each player, namely, the entrepreneur, the bank, and the advance buyer. We also found that the higher prices of the advance purchase products in the traditio regime can be compensated by better credit terms. An interesting policy implication is that there is no competitive advantage for either the seller or buyer in a contract regime compared to a traditio regime. Earlier analyses have incorrectly used market prices to determine the advantage of each regime, which may be misleading and biased towards the contract regime. A more accurate method is to compare the initial decisions to invest, which, in our analysis, are equivalent in both regimes.

The second policy implication refers to the possibility of fraud. The traditio regime should be preferred if there is a weak enforcement of corporate governance, i.e. when we relax the assumption that the creditor and the buyer are independent, and instead concur that the creditor has prior knowledge about a possible project failure, but the bank does not. Such fraudulent behaviour is not feasible under a traditio regime. Revealing fraud in a contract regime by comparing the negotiated prices and market prices is challenging when the bargaining strengths of each party and the degree of product customisation made for the buyer are unknowns.

Our conclusions regarding the preferable principle are based on a question of who should be given priority between two different parties—the advance buyers and the other creditors. Our result, showing equality between the two regimes, is supported empirically by the fact that neither regime dominates the other when considering the choices of different countries. For example, competing, but very similar neighbouring countries such as Sweden and Finland, can use different principles without either of them having an economic disadvantage over the other. Since we conclude that the two regimes are equivalent, it is not strange that different countries have made different choices. As we have pointed out (in Sect. 2), there are also other aspects to consider in the choice of principle. The choice is to some degree dependent on the legal systematic aspects. These aspects vary between legal systems and jurisdictions. The fact that one jurisdiction can use both principles for different circumstances can be viewed from this perspective. It is also possible that in most jurisdictions using the traditio principle, it is allowed and common for the parties, and some branches of industry, to depart from the traditio requirement and agree to apply the contract regime when it seems to suit the situation better.