Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-qxdb6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-26T10:28:18.866Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Peace is a form of cooperation, and so are the cultural technologies which make peace possible

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 January 2024

Julien Lie-Panis*
Affiliation:
Institut Jean Nicod, Département d'études cognitives, Ecole normale supérieure, Université PSL, EHESS, CNRS, Paris, France jlie@protonmail.com https://sites.google.com/view/julien-lie-panis jeanbaptisteandre@gmail.com http://jb.homepage.free.fr/
Jean-Baptiste André
Affiliation:
Institut Jean Nicod, Département d'études cognitives, Ecole normale supérieure, Université PSL, EHESS, CNRS, Paris, France jlie@protonmail.com https://sites.google.com/view/julien-lie-panis jeanbaptisteandre@gmail.com http://jb.homepage.free.fr/
*
*Corresponding author.

Abstract

While necessary parts of the puzzle, cultural technologies are insufficient to explain peace. They are a form of second-order cooperation – a cooperative interaction designed to incentivize first-order cooperation. We propose an explanation for peacemaking cultural technologies, and therefore peace, based on the reputational incentives for second-order cooperation.

Type
Open Peer Commentary
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Axelrod, R., & Hamilton, W. D. (1981). The evolution of cooperation. Science (New York, N.Y.), 211(4489), 13901396.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fry, D. P., Souillac, G., Liebovitch, L., Coleman, P. T., Agan, K., Nicholson-Cox, E., … Strauss, S. (2021). Societies within peace systems avoid war and build positive intergroup relationships. Humanities and Social Sciences Communications, 8(1), 17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garfield, Z. H., Schacht, R., Post, E. R., Ingram, D., Uehling, A., & Macfarlan, S. J. (2021). The content and structure of reputation domains across human societies: A view from the evolutionary social sciences. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 376(1838), 20200296.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Garfield, Z. H., Syme, K. L., & Hagen, E. H. (2020). Universal and variable leadership dimensions across human societies. Evolution and Human Behavior, 41(5), 397414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glowacki, L., & Gonc, K. (2013). Customary institutions and traditions in pastoralist societies: Neglected potential for conflict resolution. Conflict Trends, 2013(1), 2632.Google Scholar
Glowacki, L., & von Rueden, C. (2015). Leadership solves collective action problems in small-scale societies. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 370(1683), 20150010.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gurven, M., Allen-Arave, W., Hill, K., & Hurtado, M. (2000). “It's a wonderful life”: Signaling generosity among the Ache of Paraguay. Evolution and Human Behavior, 21(4), 263282.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hamilton, W. D. (1963). The evolution of altruistic behavior. The American Naturalist, 97(896), 354356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, J., & Muthukrishna, M. (2021). The origins and psychology of human cooperation. Annual Review of Psychology, 72, 207240.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lie-Panis, J., & André, J. B. (2022). Cooperation as a signal of time preferences. Proceedings of the Royal Society B, 289(1973), 20212266.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mell, H., Baumard, N., & André, J. B. (2021). Time is money. Waiting costs explain why selection favors steeper time discounting in deprived environments. Evolution and Human Behavior, 42(4), 379387.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. C. (1991). Institutions. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1), 97112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nowak, M. A., & Sigmund, K. (1998). Evolution of indirect reciprocity by image scoring. Nature, 393(6685), 573577.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Panchanathan, K., & Boyd, R. (2003). A tale of two defectors: The importance of standing for evolution of indirect reciprocity. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 224(1), 115126.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Persson, A., Rothstein, B., & Teorell, J. (2013). Why anticorruption reforms fail – Systemic corruption as a collective action problem. Governance, 26(3), 449471.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powers, S. T., Van Schaik, C. P., & Lehmann, L. (2016). How institutions shaped the last major evolutionary transition to large-scale human societies. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 371(1687), 20150098.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Singh, M., Wrangham, R., & Glowacki, L. (2017). Self-interest and the design of rules. Human Nature, 28, 457480.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sugiyama, L. S. (2004). Illness, injury, and disability among Shiwiar forager-horticulturalists: Implications of health-risk buffering for the evolution of human life history. American Journal of Physical Anthropology, 123(4), 371389.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
von Rueden, C. (2014). The roots and fruits of social status in small-scale human societies. In J. Cheng, J. Tracy & C. Anderson (Eds.), The Psychology of Social Status (pp. 179200). Springer. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4939-0867-7_9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yamagishi, T. (1986). The provision of a sanctioning system as a public good. Journal of Personality and social Psychology, 51(1), 110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar